Another limitation of the cost-benefit approach adopted by
smart grid advocates is that it reduces benefits to dollars. But
an additional dollar to higher-income consumers has less
additional benefit (in the language of economists, utility) than
it does to lower-income consumers. Presumably, utilities and
their vendors, shareholders, and executives are wealthier than
low-income consumers. So, if the objective is to provide the
greatest good or utility to the greatest number, the types of
smart grid technologies that benefit lower-income consumers
should be considered and rolled out first because a small
improvement in their financial situation is a large benefit or
utility. There may be many smart grid technologies and
applications that do benefit lower-income and other
disadvantaged groups, for instance by improving reliability,
reducing electricity consumption and utility bills, and
improving monitoring of vital health equipment that some
depend upon, among others.
Another common definition of equity within the cost-benefit
framework is that costs and benefits should be aligned. That
is, customers who add costs to the system—for instance, due
to high peak usage—should pay the additional costs due to
generating and delivering electricity during peak hours. It
may be, as some have argued, that in the case of smart meters
combined with some form of dynamic pricing, lower income
customers would be better off, at least in aggregate, because
they use less on-peak energy than larger customers [28].
Under existing uniform rates, therefore, these lower income
customers are paying for some of the costs associated with the
peak consumption by higher income customers. If this turns
out to be the case when the costs of smart meters are
included, it would be fortuitous because it aligns with
another, and very different, equity definition under which
268