$30,000 to $39,999 13.6 12.2% 11,431 $1,143 3.3%
$40,000 to $49,999 11.0 9.9% 11,658 $1,166 2.6%
$50,000 to $74,999 19.8 17.8% 12,440 $1,244 2.0%
$75,000 to $99,999 10.6 9.5% 13,559 $1,356 1.5%
$100,000 or More 14.2 12.8% 15,382 $1,538 1.5%
Total 111.1 100%
Source: 2005 Residential Energy Consumption Survey, Energy Information
Agency
This chapter begins by describing and characterizing smart
grid, an elusive term that perhaps defies precise definition.
Some have approached this definitional challenge not by
describing the technologies that smart grid encompasses, but
by describing the desired attributes, as Hauser and Crandall
do in Chapter 1 of this volume. If smart grid means a
generation, transmission, and distribution system that is more
intelligent than today's because it takes advantage of the
leapfrog improvements in informational and computational
technologies, it is a useful term. If the term is used to set up a
false choice between “smart” and “dumb,” rather than to be
informative, it is pejorative and brings discussion to a halt.
Next, important questions related to smart grid underscore
that smart grid technologies and policies raise serious and
legitimate concerns. Some have argued that dynamic pricing,
which smart meters could enable, is more equitable than
current flat rates because low-income customers would have
lower electricity bills (e.g., as argued by Faruqui in Chapter
3). Others question whether residential ratepayers would
benefit from advance metering infrastructure [4], [5] and [6].
To what extent, if at all, equity analysis of dynamic pricing
bears on smart grid more generally is open for discussion.
There is nothing close to a majority view, let alone a near
consensus, that these technologies should be adopted. As one
251