8
n e o l i b e r a l af r i c a
patterns of international political economy is slight, but shifts
and changes in the latter make a great deal of difference to the
former.
The politics of international debt provide a rough and ready
diagnostic of Africa’s economic vulnerability. A slightly dated but
illustrative example of this is the debt crisis that emerged in the
early 1980s. In 1982/3, the failure of Brazil and Mexico to maintain
payments on debt to the World Bank and the IMF triggered a series
of responses by the Bretton Woods institutions, the American
government, and other institutions to reschedule, open new lines of
credit, and try to secure currency stability in the large but highly
indebted economies of Latin America. During the same period,
similar degrees of debt peonage in small African economies barely
registered on the world stage: instead, the World Bank and the
IMF were given pretty much an autonomous remit to implement
economic conditionalities on distressed economies whilst debt
was managed (not often reduced) by the World Bank, the IMF
and the Paris Club of bilateral donors. For the US Treasury, the
international economic think-tanks, banks, investors and financial
journalists, economic meltdown in African states mattered little.
A related example can be found in a more recent comparison
with Southeast Asia, which accrued large amounts of debt during
the 1990s. Nevertheless, whereas most African countries had a
debt-to-export ratio of about 200 per cent, the proportions in
Southeast Asia were significantly lower: 34 per cent in Malaysia and
78 per cent in Thailand (African Development Bank 2006: 13).
These two regional comparisons reveal how international debt
serves as a diagnostic of the political economy of Africa’s economic
fragility. In the first case, we saw how extremely debt-distressed
African economies merited only the most meagre ‘rescue packages’,
executed through the World Bank and the IMF and attached to
punitive conditionalities (see Chapters 2 and 4) because these
economies were of only marginal importance to the ‘core’ regions
of global capitalism. In the second example, we saw how large