THE CONTROL OF PATRONAGE AND POLICY
145
communications make themselves felt after 1730’.
84
While Bourde points out the
necessity of a detailed study of the Orry administration, he tends to agree with
Carré, Gaxotte, Muret, Lhéritier and Marion that, although it was not a great
ministry, it was ‘nevertheless a “good” ancien régime ministry’.
85
This view should be questioned—not in the sense that the economic achievement
itself should be denied, but in the sense that it is possibly incorrect to attribute the
economic and commercial expansion to the initiative of Orry. Even conceding, with
Bourde, the importance of such subordinates as Fagon, intendant of commerce, and
Daniel Trudaine, it can be argued that the responsibility may lie in an altogether
different direction.
86
Government stimulation and concern has been shown to have
had a very limited impact on production, and in some cases was detrimental. It may
also be suggested, first, that Orry was an excessively traditionally minded finance
minister of the ancien régime and therefore unlikely to have thought up important
commercial policies at a time when he was content to implement badly calculated
financial policies; second, that in matters of policy he was kept in such
subordination to Fleury that Fleury and not he should take the credit, since the
cardinal displayed a real concern for commerce; and third, that since foreign trade
was a more important sector of the economy than internal trade according to the
terms in which national wealth was then calculated, Maurepas played at least as
important a role as Orry.
Mosser, who has studied the intendants of finance, concluded that
‘administrative and judicial business was decided upon by the controller general
and by the intendants of finance’, and that in Orry’s period the assemblies of the
intendants (from which other ministers were absent) were of great importance, as
was shown above.
87
Nevertheless, it remains true that neither she nor Antoine has
tackled the issue of the genesis of economic and financial policy and of the
relationship of the contrôleur général with the premier ministre. Antoine has shown
that of the 3,500 to 4,000 arrêts du conseil promulgated each year, more than two
thirds concerned finance. Of these, ‘it can be estimated that on average, out of eight
to ten arrêts de finance [financial rulings in council], only one was the result of an
examination in Council according to the appropriate forms…In finance, the council
was most often a fiction’.
88
The implications of these studies appear to be that in an administrative
monarchy (if indeed historians are correct in singling out administrative rather than
social processes as its most important characteristic) matters of finance tended to
escape the control of all but the contrôleur général himself. Statistically, this conclusion
would be well supported. But these inferences should be treated with caution. The
statistics do not show the relative importance of the individual arrêts du conseil and
that kind of precise evidence is lacking for this period, owing to the destruction of
the archives. So it is impossible to deduce from the statistics that the contrôleur général
made decisions on matters of policy alone or with his intendants, without
consultation with other ministers.
89
The fact that the conseil des finances met less and
less frequently may not necessarily mean that policy escaped the attention of Louis
XV and Fleury, only that as policy remained unchanged and unoriginal, there was