Назад
COMMERCE AND CITIES 389
transported to Kyoto.
95
They were quickly joined by several thousand
cultivators from Omi and neighboring provinces. Although no histori-
cal document tells exactly why this uprising began and spread so
quickly, there is no doubt that the main reason was the poor harvest of
the previous year that caused disease to spread and the debt burden of
the teamsters and cultivators to become even heavier. The cultivators
involved in the uprising "took the records of their debt and burned
them" and "attacked, in the name of tokusei [virtuous
rule],
sakaya,
doso,
and temples and robbed them of valuables." They had to be
subdued by the warriors dispatched by several daimyo in response to
the urgent request of the shaken bakufu.
96
Although only a few ikki were as large as this one,
97
there were
twenty-six large ikki each involving at least a few hundred people,
between 1428 and the end of the century. A dozen or so of the later
uprisings involved more and more warriors, indicating both the effects
that monetization and the growth of commerce had on their economic
lot and the further weakening of the bakufu. The tokuseirei of the
fifteenth century were perhaps the offspring of a marriage between a
growing commerce that made money even more essential to the daily
lives of all and a central political authority that was gradually becom-
ing less central and less authoritative.
The Kitano sake-malt (kdji) za demonstrates the effects of the chang-
ing political reality of the period on commerce in general and on the za
in particular.
98
Sanctioned by the Kitano Shrine, a branch of the powerful En-
ryakuji, by the mid-fourteenth century, this za was actively engaged in
selling malt. Documents written during the 1390s, however, show that
its exclusive right to supply malt to about 350 sake makers in most
parts of Kyoto was no longer "protected" by the shrine alone. In 1388,
the bakufu began to levy taxes in exchange for a decree supporting the
za's continued monopoly rights. Clearly, even with the backing of the
Enryakuji, the shrine by this time had become unable to prevent the
bakufu from sharing in the za's profits.
Then, during the early decades of the fifteenth century, the za
95 This is the so-called Seicho do-ikki. An excellent description of it can be found in Sasaki,
Muromachi bakufu, pp.
178-81.
96 Ibid., p. 179.
97 Another major ikki occurred in 1441 and is called Kakitsu do-ikki. A short but good summary
of it can be found in ibid., pp.
181-3.
98 For descriptions of this za, see Yamamura, "The Development of Za," pp. 454-63, and the
works of Japanese scholars that it cites.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
390 THE GROWTH OF COMMERCE
found that many sake makers were providing their own malt instead of
buying it from the za. This apparently occurred because the demand
for sake had risen so that it became more profitable for each sake
maker to build a malt chamber rather than to buy malt from
the za
and
because the sake brewers evidently judged the Enryakuji's power to
have so declined that they could safely challenge the za's monopoly
rights.
The sake makers had, however, underestimated the bakufu's reluc-
tance to become involved at this time in open conflict with the
Enryakuji. In 1419, the bakufu affirmed its support of the za and
allowed it to destroy nearly fifty malt chambers that had been con-
structed by the sake makers. But as the bakufu continued to show
signs of increasing strength and stability in the early decades of the
fifteenth century, the sake makers, motivated by the possibility of
larger profits, continued to build malt chambers as if
to
test the limits
of the delicate balance of political power then existing between the
bakufu and the large temples. Between 1420 and the mid-i44Os, the
bakufu continued to allow the za to destroy malt chambers when they
were discovered, thus indicating that the bakufu, at least on the sur-
face,
was still maintaining its political stance of not challenging the
Enryakuji's hold on the za.
The sake makers saw the bakufu's actions as an indication of less
than wholehearted support for the za and assumed that sooner or later
the bakufu would choose to support them. They knew that they were a
more lucrative source of tax income for the bakufu than was the za
which owed its primary allegiance to the temple. Meanwhile, malt
chambers continued to be built and destroyed.
This,
then, was the background of the celebrated malt incident of
1444-5.
1° the fall of 1444, the sake makers openly disregarded the
za's monopoly rights and ceased to buy malt.
The za
members immedi-
ately petitioned the bakufu to enforce their monopoly. They locked
themselves in the Kitano temple to await a favorable decision. Despite
this drastic measure, the occupation of a sacred temple, the bakufu
wavered. To abandon the za was the more profitable alternative, but
the bakufu was uncertain whether it wished to risk an uprising of
temples, which could prove costly to
subdue.
After sixty
days
of indeci-
sion, the bakufu resolved to support the za. However, because the
bakufu had clearly shown by its delay that it might be persuaded to
rule against the za, the sake makers of eastern Kyoto presented a
counterpetition asking for permission to make their own malt. Hear-
ing of this, the members of the za again locked themselves in the
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
COMMERCE AND CITIES 391
temple, vowing not to leave until the bakufu reaffirmed its decision
favorable to the za.
This time it was the za that miscalculated the remaining power of
the Enryakuji and the extent to which the bakufu could be coerced.
Angered by the za's action, the bakufu ordered one of its leading
supporters, Hatakeyama, to drive the za members out of the temple.
Hatakeyama's troops clashed with the za members, who failed to win
the support of the Enryakuji's well-known soldier-monks. The skir-
mish left forty dead, and the surviving za members fled the temple.
Some of the za members fleeing the conflict set fire to large structures
in western Kyoto, causing a major blaze that reduced much of the
western half of the city to ashes. The za was abolished, and it was not
until after the Onin War that some of its members were allowed to
return to Kyoto. This episode tells us that a political force powerful
enough to secure the profits from the increased sale of a product or
from increased commerce in general found it more profitable to forgo
a share in the monopolistic profits of a za that had clearly become
detrimental to the growth of commerce.
To be sure, many za in Kyoto continued
to
operate by paying more to
the bakufu, and many survived because they did not have a competing
group able to promise more to the bakufu. In many regions, this cen-
tury of transition
was a
period of
ad hoc
arrangements that depended on
the strength of the regional warrior class, on the degree to which the
bakufu's authority was felt, and on the residual strength of court nobles
and temples. In many cases, as the price for survival, the za paid more
dues to the bakufu or to the regional power, and in others, temples and
court
nobles were
forced
to
forgo dues from
some regions
while continu-
ing to receive income from others. The trend, however, was
unmistakable - the amount of dues that the za received from temples
and court nobles was fast diminishing. This happened simply because
as the fifteenth century progressed and the za monopolies were more
often challenged, each za had to appeal to the bakufu or a regional
power for the support that
its
original sponsors could
no
longer provide.
Finally, as the growth of commerce continued, integrating more mar-
kets within a region and even across regions, the political powers and
all who traded in the markets came to realize that the varying measures
of weight, length, and volume being used seriously impeded market
transactions. The absence of a uniform measure of volume (cubic
measure) was especially troublesome.
Even though nearly a dozen measures of weight and length were
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
392 THE GROWTH OF COMMERCE
used (to measure land and such widely traded commodities as silk,
cloth, and iron), this problem could be overcome: All these measures
could, if
necessary,
be converted and made comparable. In most cases,
these were measures used since the
ritsuryo
period, and the specialized
use of some measures, such as those for cloth and iron, were pertinent
to only a few specialists.
But the same was not the case for a cubic measure, which was
important during this period because it was used by all who measured
rice in paying and receiving taxes and rents and also in trading gener-
ally. Stated simply, the cubic measure of
rice,
the
tnasu
(square wooden
container), had grown over time; that is, for measuring the same
nominal quantity of rice, the
tnasu
increased by a factor of approxi-
mately 2.5 during the medieval period. For example, in terms of the
measure used in the Tokugawa period, one sho of rice had changed
from approximately 0.4
sho
in the tenth century to almost 1.0
sho
by
the mid-fifteenth century. And to compound the problem, any precise
conversion was virtually impossible because the size of the
tnasu
grew
gradually from the tenth century to the early sixteenth century by
region and even by
shoen.
Some large temples also used differing sizes
of
tnasu,
depending on the purposes for which each was used.
It is not difficult to speculate why this occurred. Because rice was
principally a means of paying dues, it was to the advantage of each
dues recipient to enlarge the tnasu used in measuring those dues.
Undoubtedly the rate and rapidity of the increase in size closely re-
flected the political or military power cf each recipient.
Here, it is useful to recall the hypothesis offered earlier to expls±i
the use of
erizeni
by various levels cf political powers to increase ne
real burden of dues with minimal political costs. This situation is
analogous in that enlarging the size cf
tnasu
gradually over time was
also a means to enlarge the real burden of the dues with minimal
political costs. Such a hypothesis also explains why the effort made by
Emperor Gosanjo in 1072 to standardize the size of the
tnasu
- an
attempt to require the use of the "decreed
tnasu"
(senji-tnasu)
- had
little effect and why no political power, either the bakufu or the
shugo
daimyo who were in positions to standardize the measure, did not
make a similar effort.
It is unlikely that the dues payers failed to detect the change in the
size of the
tnasu
by which their dues were measured. Possible explana-
tions for their accepting the larger
tnasu
from dues payers range from
the dues recipients' power over the dues payers, to the latter's willing-
ness to accept this means of increasing dues rather than more explicit
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
COMMERCE AND CITIES 393
and potentially more burdensome means such as increasing the rate of
dues or resurveying the arable land. Or it might have been a mixture of
these two reasons. The second reason should not be rejected, because
agricultural productivity was rising from the mid-thirteenth century
on and dues payers were better able to accept the de facto increase in
the dues through the larger size of the masu. And there is no record of
uprising or petition expressing dissatisfaction with the bigger dues
resulting from the masu's increased size.
However, by the mid- to late fifteenth century and into the sixteenth
century, more and more
shugo
daimyo and then
sengoku
daimyo began
to try to standardize such measures. Their motivation was to encour-
age the growth of commerce, as typified by their adoption of rakuichi-
rakuza (promotion of less impeded commerce and limitation of the ,
za's power), a policy they adopted beginning in the mid-sixteenth
century. And it is known that before an effective nationwide standard-
ization of measures of weight and length was adopted in the Tokugawa
period, several shugo daimyo and sengoku daimyo actively promoted
standardized measures their respective domains.
Again, the cubic measure was the most difficult to standardize.
Although limited historical evidence makes it difficult to make any
definite observations, it appears that from the mid-fifteenth century
on, the regional powers and especially Nobunaga, the first of the
unifiers, encouraged the use of kyo-masu (Kyoto masu), the masu that
by then was widely used in the capital, the center of commerce as well
as the seat of the Muromachi bakufu. The kyo-masu differed slightly in
size (with a maximum margin of nearly 5 percent), but one sho of kyo-
masu was roughly equivalent to one sho by the Tokugawa measure (the
kyo-masu later became the basis on which the Tokugawa cubic mea-
sures were established).
In addition, because of the problems with cubic measures in this
period, in virtually no cases is it possible to ascertain correctly the
exact amount of dues collected in rice. If an estimate is to be made over
any length of time, even for a single shoen, let alone broader in-
terregional and intertemporal comparisons, one must allow for the
growth in the size of the masu at differing paces and magnitudes
throughout most of the medieval period."
99 The most useful source on the medieval measures is by Hashimoto Mampei, Keisoku no
bunkashi (Tokyo: Asahi Shimbunsha, 1982), pp. 269-334. The seminal study on the subject
is by Hogetsu Keigo sensei kanreki kinenkai, ed., Chusei ryoseishi no kenkyu (Tokyo:
Yoshikawa kobunkan, 1961). The latter contains analyses of all of the significant historical
evidence relating to the medieval measures.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
394 THE GROWTH OF COMMERCE
CONCLUSION
This chapter has examined the growth of commerce in medieval Japan
and how the many changes that resulted from it transformed the
economy from one with only limited market activities in the capital
region into an economy with an increasing number of six-day markets
throughout the nation.
This transformation was accompanied by such readily visible results
as an increase in both the size and number of urban centers; significant
institutional developments typified by the rise and growth of za and
toimaru; the spread of monetization from the capital to villages
throughout the nation; increased specialization of merchants and arti-
sans who produced more and more products; and the development of a
transportation network linking all parts of the nation and including a
growing number of persons engaged in transporting goods by both
water and land.
Less visible but fundamental to this transformation was
a
steady and
at times rapid increase in agricultural productivity which began in the
second half of the thirteenth century. This was enabled principally by
the more intensive use of paddies, including double cropping and even
triple cropping in some regions, and to a decreasing number of pad-
dies lost to flooding or drought, owing to improvements in irrigation
and water control. In addition, the economy as a whole was more
productive and efficient. People became much more aware of the ef-
fects that changes in prices could have on their lives, of markets where
they could buy many more goods that others produced more effi-
ciently than they themselves could; and of the many ways that they
could increase their income, by selling products or services or lending
money.
To be sure, the benefits of commercialization and monetization also
produced conflicts of interest between the za and their challengers,
between lenders and borrowers, and between dues recipients and pay-
ers.
Such conflicts took many forms. The za sought protection from
would-be competitors, and the za patrons attempted to gain a greater
share of their profits. Through
tokuseirei,
bakufu tried to protect war-
riors indebted to moneylenders, and dues payers and others who felt
victimized by the changes in the economy expressed their dissatisfac-
tion and demands through ikki. The prevailing political realities of
these three and a half centuries played a crucial role in determining the
specific forms these symptoms would take and the degree to which
their costs would affect the polity's future course.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
CONCLUSION 395
Sengoku Japan inherited a highly commercialized and monetized
economy, but one that was still coping with rapid political and eco-
nomic change and the symptoms and costs of such growth. The most
interesting aspect of sixteenth-century Japanese history is how the
sengoku
daimyo, who reaped the benefits of the growing commerce,
were forced to deal with both.
100
loo On the erizeni issues and other politicoeconomic developments in the Sengoku period, see
Kozo Yamamura, "Returns on Unification: Economic Growth in Japan, 1550-1650," in
John Whitney Hall, Nagahara Keiji, and Kozo Yamamura, eds., Japan Before Tokugawa
(Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1981), pp. 327-72.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
CHAPTER
9
JAPAN AND EAST ASIA
In this chapter
I
shall describe and analyze Japan's relations during
the Kamakura and Muromachi periods with various countries of East
Asia and their governments, including the Sung, Yuan, and Ming
dynasties
of
China, the Koryo and Yi dynasties
of
Korea, and
the
Ryukyu Islands.
My
descriptions
and
analyses focus primarily
on
Japan's international political relations, particularly Japan's relation-
ship with
its
Asian neighbors, the effect
of
this relationship on Ja-
pan's internal political developments, and, conversely, the influence
of Japan's internal politics on its international relations.
1
Because my
research interests lie mainly
in
the Kamakura period,
I
shall discuss
developments
of
that period more extensively than those of the later
Muromachi period.
JAPAN'S INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
IN
EAST ASIA
Around the tenth century the motive force in East Asia shifted from
the Han People of China to the northern nomadic tribes, often called
the conquest dynasties.
In
the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries,
East Asian history centered on the rise and fall of the Mongol Empire.
The Southern Sung (i 127-1279) was reestablished after China's terri-
tory was reduced by the consecutive invasions of the Liao and Chin,
which generated
a
financial crisis owing
to
the massive military ex-
penses. The Southern Sung, whose resources and level of productivity
were lower than those of northern China, inherited the developments
that took place
in
various industries during and following the domi-
1 There
are a
number
or
works
on the
methodology
of
studying East Asian relations;
the
following cover the thirteenth through the sixteenth centuries: Nakamura Hidetaka, "Jusan,
yonseki no Toa josei to Mongoru no shurai," in Iwanami koza Nihon no rekishi, vol.
6
(chusei
2) (Tokyo: Iwanami shoten, 1963),
pp.
4-9; Nissen kankeishi
no
kenkyu, vol.i (Tokyo:
Yoshikawa kobunkan, 1965), pp.
2-7
(reprint
of
the preceding); Toma Seita, Higashi Ajia
sekai no keisei (Tokyo: Shunjusha, 1966); Tanaka Takeo, Chusei laigai kankeishi (Tokyo: Tokyo
daigaku shuppankai, 1975), pp. 10-20; Sasaki Ginya. "Higashi Ajia boekiken
no
keisei
to
kokusai ninshiki,"
in
Iwanami koza Nihon rekishi, vol.
7
(chusei 3) (Tokyo: Iwanami shoten,
'976), pp. 100-10.
396
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
JAPAN'S INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 397
nance of the Northern Sung (960-1127) and vigorously promoted
foreign trade in hopes of resolving its
financial
crisis.
Japan did not have official diplomatic relations with either the South-
ern Sung or the Koryo (918-1391) dynasties. But it did enjoy close
cultural and economic ties with both China and Korea, especially the
Southern Sung dynasty, through its commercial maritime activity
along the China seacoast which formed one link in the East Asian
trading sphere. This was the reason that the Mongols - who had domi-
nated Koryo in creating a new international order in East Asia after
their conquest of Southern Sung - tried first to entice Japan into the
new order and then to conquer it. Thus, the Mongol invasions were
attempts to force Japan to enter international politics.
The Kamakura bakufu assumed diplomatic powers during the inva-
sions and undertook official trade with the Yiian dynasty of China
(1279-1368) in response to the Mongol's official intensification of its
trade policy during the late Kamakura period. This presaged the diplo-
macy of the succeeding Muromachi bakufu which received investiture
from China's Ming dynasty (1368-1644) and was included in the
Sinocentric international order. The Mongol invasions strengthened
the authoritarian tendencies of the Hojo family, which held the real
power in the Kamakura bakufu, and presented the Hojo with a num-
ber of problems beyond their administrative capabilities, finally caus-
ing the bakufu to topple in 1333.
The Kemmu regime, which destroyed the Kamakura bakufu and
lasted only two years, led Japan into the protracted internal conflict
between the Northern and Southern Courts during the Nambokucho
period (1333-92). During this sixty-year period Ashikaga Takauji
founded the Muromachi bakufu. The war between the courts during
the fourteenth century served to consolidate the power of the
Muromachi bakufu. During this struggle in 1350, the attacks of Japa-
nese pirates
(wako)
began in earnest, spreading from the Korean penin-
sula south along the China coast.
2
The wako's activities spanned four
centuries and occurred in two phases.
The early phase of
wako
activity began in the thirteenth century and
extended to the second half of the fourteenth, corresponding to the
Nambokucho and early Muromachi periods in Japan, the late Koryo
2 There are many works dealing with the wako, and a number of works on Koryo, Choson, and
Ming relations with Japan also touch on the wako. See especially Tanaka Takeo, Chusei kaigai
koshoshi
no kenkyu (Tokyo: Tokyo daigaku shuppankai, 1959) and Wako to kango boeki (Tokyo:
Shibundo, 1961); Kobata Atsushi, "Kango boeki to wako," in Iwanami koza Nihon rekishi,
vol.
7 (chusei 3) (Tokyo: Iwanami shoten, 1963); and Ishihara Michihiro, Wako (Tokyo:
Yoshikawa kobunkan, 1964).
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
398 JAPAN AND EAST ASIA
and early Yi (i392-1910) in Korea, and the late Yuan to early Ming in
China. Although the Korean peninsula was their main theater of activ-
ity, the wako reached the China coast as well. During the first phase of
wako activity, the indigenous Chinese Ming dynasty emerged in China
after destroying the intruding Mongol Yuan dynasty, and on the Ko-
rean peninsula, the Yi dynasty succeeded the Koryo dynasty. The
wako problem was a force in the founding of both these dynasties in
China and Korea, and it
is
evident that relations among Japan, Korea,
and Ming China were established as a result of the
wako
problem. In
Southeast Asia, several new kingdoms were established in the four-
teenth and fifteenth centuries, ushering in an era of revolution and
disorder previously unknown. The second major phase of
wako
activ-
ity occurred in the early to mid-sixteenth century.
The different stages of political, economic, and cultural develop-
ment in these Asian countries occurred within a unified international
order revolving around Ming China. This order was referred to as the
tribute system
and involved the exchange of tribute and largess between
China and other "barbarian" nations. Ming policy forbade Chinese
citizens to leave the country as part of
this
tribute system, but this only
stimulated the development of a flourishing trade in the newly risen
Ryukyu kingdom (present-day Okinawa) and the overseas Chinese
communities to the south. The Ryukyus achieved unmatched prosper-
ity as an intermediary in the trade among Southeast Asia, Japan, and
Korea. The Ming policy forbidding overseas travel failed, and in the
sixteenth century during the Chia-ching era (1522-66), wako flour-
ished along the southeastern China coast. But with the arrival of
Euro-
pean ships, East Asian international relations underwent a dramatic
change.
FOREIGN RELATIONS AT THE FOUNDING OF THE
KAMAKURA BAKUFU
Kyushu had been a base of political power for the Taira family. During
the Gempei War (1180-5), however, Minamoto Yoritomo's younger
brother Noriyori overthrew the Heishi forces in Kyushu. In 10/1185
Noriyori left Kyushu to return to Kamakura and presented the retired
emperor Goshirakawa and Yoritomo with many gifts imported from
the mainland to Kyushu, reconfirming for both men the importance of
Kyushu in foreign trade.
3
Although initially an eastern power, the
3 These gifts included Chinese brocade, damask, silks, Sung silver coins, tea, ink, utensils, and
matting. There is also mention of the Southern Court in a deed of sale of some land belonging
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008