X. Mergers, Corporate
34. Control Governance,
operating cash flows can turn to the main bank or other keiretsu companies for fi-
nancing. This avoids the cost or possible bad-news signal of a public sale of securities.
Second, when a keiretsu firm falls into financial distress, with insufficient cash to pay
bills or fund necessary capital investments, a “workout” can usually be arranged.
New management can be brought in from elsewhere in the group, and financing can
be obtained, again “internally.”
Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein tracked capital expenditure programs of a large
sample of Japanese firms—many, but not all, members of keiretsus. The keiretsu
companies’ investments were more stable and less exposed to the ups and downs of
operating cash flows or to episodes of financial distress.
45
It seems that the financial
support of the keiretsus enabled their members to invest for the long run.
The Japanese system of corporate control has its disadvantages too, notably for
outside investors, who have very little influence. Japanese managers’ compensa-
tion is rarely tied to shareholder returns. Takeovers are unthinkable. Japanese com-
panies have been particularly stingy with cash dividends; this was hardly a con-
cern when growth was rapid and stock prices were stratospheric but is a serious
issue for the future.
Corporate Ownership around the World
The theory of modern finance is most readily applied to public corporations with
shares traded in active and efficient capital markets. The theory assumes that
stockholders’ interests are protected, so that ownership can be dispersed across
thousands of minority stockholders. The protection comes from managers’ incen-
tives, particularly compensation tied to stock price; from supervision by the board
of directors; and by the threat of hostile takeover of poorly performing companies.
This is a reasonable description of the corporate sector in the U.S., UK, and other
“Anglo-Saxon” countries such as Canada and Australia. But as Germany and
Japan illustrate, it is not an accurate description elsewhere. Corporate ownership
in Germany is typical of continental Europe. The ownership diagram for a large
French company would resemble Figure 34.3.
46
The financial architecture of public companies in “Anglo-Saxon” economies
may be the exception, not the rule. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer sur-
veyed the ownership of the largest companies in 27 developed countries. They
found that “except in economies with very good shareholder protection, relatively
few of these firms are widely held. Rather these firms are typically controlled by
families or the State,” or in some cases by financial institutions.
47
This finding has various possible interpretations. The first is obvious: Protection
for outside minority stockholders is a prerequisite for dispersed ownership and a
broad and active stock market. Second, in countries that lack effective legal pro-
tection for minority stockholders, concentrated ownership may be the only feasi-
ble financial architecture.
986 PART X
Mergers, Corporate Control, and Governance
45
T. Hoshi, A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein, “Corporate Structure, Liquidity and Investment: Evidence
from Japanese Industrial Groups,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (February 1991), pp. 33–60, and
“The Role of Banks in Reducing the Costs of Financial Distress in Japan,” Journal of Financial Economics
27 (September 1990), pp. 67–88.
46
See J. Franks and C. Mayer, “Corporate Ownership and Control in the U. K., Germany and France,”
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 9 (Winter 1997), pp. 30–45.
47
R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer, “Corporate Ownership around the World,” Journal of
Finance 59 (April 1999), pp. 471–517.