
The Old
Poor
Law and
the Agricultural
Labor Market 125
administrators to pursue a policy with an economical alteration of poor
relief and independent income for the labourer" (1978: 105).
In Chapter 1,1 argued that the major function of outdoor relief
was
to
provide unemployment benefits for seasonally unemployed agricultural
laborers. The decline of cottage industry, and the loss of land from
enclosures and engrossment, magnified the problem of seasonality in
grain-producing areas. To maintain their laborers' income at its previous
level, farmers anxious to secure an adequate peak-season labor force
either had to raise agricultural wage rates or agree to grant poor relief to
workers not needed during the winter months.
The model developed in Chapter 3 showed that contracts containing
outdoor relief and layoffs dominated alternative contracts in areas
where the demand for labor fluctuated sharply over the crop cycle, while
yearlong wage contracts were dominant in areas where the demand for
labor remained fairly steady throughout the year. One should find, there-
fore,
that per capita relief expenditures were higher in grain-producing
areas than in pasture-farming areas. Moreover, the value of the compen-
sation package, in terms of utility, that labor-hiring farmers had to offer
in order to retain their workers was found to be negatively related to the
cost of migrating from the parish to an urban industrial area. Assuming
that cost of migration can be proxied by distance, wage rates or relief
expenditures should have been lower the farther a parish was from an
urban labor market.
Employment opportunities for women and children in cottage indus-
try or allotments of land reduced the value of the compensation package
farmers had to offer their workers. In response to these other income
sources, poor relief expenditures might have declined, as Davies, Eden,
and Young maintained. It is also possible, however, that labor-hiring
farmers responded to such advantages by cutting wage rates for adult
male agricultural laborers rather than by reducing relief expenditures.
The small size of rural parishes suggests that it was not difficult for
farmers to agree to do so.
2
2
For the sample of southern agricultural parishes used in the empirical analysis here, the
average number of labor-hiring farmers per parish was 16 in 1831. Because part of the
poor rate was paid by taxpayers who did not hire labor, it was in every labor-hiring
farmer's interest to respond to other income sources by reducing wages rather than relief
expenditures. Of course, non-labor-hiring taxpayers had an incentive to reduce relief
expenditures, so the extent to which farmers were able to reduce wages depended on
their political power in the parish. The regression results in Tables 4.5 and 4.6 show that
the existence of other income sources reduced both wages and relief expenditures. Note
that I am assuming that workers made decisions concerning migration based on their total