
144 An Economic History of
the
English Poor Law
ment. The "long-term . . . consolidation of farms into larger and more
efficient units" that had begun in the seventeenth century was encour-
aged by the wave of enclosures between 1760 and 1815 (Chambers and
Mingay 1966: 92). The consequent decline in the number of small land-
holders increased the political power of labor-hiring farmers. The pas-
sage of Gilbert's Act (1782) introduced
u
the principle of weighting the
right to vote according to the amount of property occupied." This princi-
ple was extended by the 1818 Parish Vestry Act, which allowed rate-
payers up to six votes in vestry, depending on their poor rate assessment
(Brundage 1978: 7, 10). Because labor-hiring farmers were generally the
largest property holders in rural parishes, their political power was sig-
nificantly increased in parishes that adopted either of these acts. The
cross-sectional evidence suggests that farmers used their increased politi-
cal power to increase relief expenditures and therefore to pass more of
their labor costs on to non-labor-hiring ratepayers.
However, the most important cause of the increase in relief expendi-
tures probably was the combination of: (1) the decline in employment
opportunities and wage rates for women and children in cottage indus-
try, and (2) the rapid increase in London wage rates. From 1795 to 1832,
real wage rates of London builders' laborers increased by 44%.
18
During
the same period, the weekly earnings of an agricultural laborer's wife
and children in cottage industry declined from perhaps 2s.-5s. to 0s.-
3s.
19
The decline in cottage industry was most pronounced in East
Anglia, but the responses to question 11 of the Rural Queries show that
employment in cottage industry was declining throughout the south. The
conclusion here that the southern labor market was well integrated in
the early nineteenth century suggests that, in response to the decline in
cottage industry and the increase in London wage rates, farmers anxious
to secure an adequate peak-season labor force had to increase laborers'
wage rates or relief expenditures. The average weekly wage of southern
agricultural laborers increased from 8.8s. in 1795 to 10.6s. in 1832, which
was barely enough to offset the decline in earnings from cottage indus-
18
Nominal wage data
for
London laborers were obtained from Schwarz (1986: 37-8).
Cost-of-living data were obtained from Lindert
and
Williamson (1985: 148-9).
19
Estimates
of
the weekly earnings
of
women and children in cottage industry in
1795
were
obtained from Eden (1797). Estimates
of
weekly earnings
in
1832 were obtained from
the responses
to
question 11
of the
Rural Queries (Parl. Papers 1834: XXX). Question
11
also contains evidence that
by
1832
cottage industry had completely disappeared from
some areas
in
which
it had
flourished
in the
late eighteenth century.
For a
discussion
of
the long-term decline
in
wage rates
and
employment opportunities
in
cottage industry
see Chapter
1,
Section
3, and
Pinchbeck (1930: 138-45, 208,
220-1,
225).