
136 An Economic History of
the
English Poor Law
should be briefly noted. Per capita relief expenditures are expected to be
determined, first of all, by the existence and magnitude of alternative
income sources, namely, employment opportunities in cottage industry,
the existence of allotments, and the expected wage income of agricul-
tural laborers. Distance from London is a proxy for cost of migration.
9
As the cost of migration increased, the cost of securing an adequate
peak-season labor force declined, which should have caused a reduction
in relief expenditures.
10
The variable FARMERS tests whether, as the
political power of labor-hiring farmers (estimated by the ratio of labor-
hiring farmers to total taxpayers) increased, they were able to pass more
of the cost of maintaining their workers on to the parish. A parish's per
capita property wealth might be a determinant of its relief generosity,
and thus is expected to have a positive effect on relief expenditures. The
variable GRAIN is a proxy for seasonality in the demand for labor. An
increase in seasonality should have increased the winter unemployment
rate and, therefore, per capita relief
expenditures.
The rate of unemploy-
ment is included as an explanatory variable in the simultaneous equa-
9
By
using distance from London
as a
proxy
for the
cost
of
migration,
I am
assuming that
London
was the
destination
for all
potential migrants from
the
agricultural south.
The
assumption
may be
incorrect
for
rural areas close
to
other southern cities. During
the
period 1801-31,
the
combined populations
of
Bath, Brighton, Bristol, Norwich, Plym-
outh, Portsmouth,
and
Southampton increased
by
174,000. However, over
the
same
period
the
population
of
London increased
by
790,000 (Mitchell
and
Deane
1962: 19,
24-7).
Deane
and
Cole (1967:
115)
found that
all
southern counties outside
the
London
area experienced
net
out-migration from 1801
to
1831, while London experienced heavy
in-migration. Thus
the
attraction
of, say,
Bristol was
not
strong enough
to
keep Glouces-
ter from losing workers
to
London. Moreover, Redford (1964: 63-6), Hunt (1973:
282-
4),
and
Pollard (1978: 107-8) agree that there
was
very little migration from
the
rural
south
to the
industrial cities
of the
northwest during this period, which suggests that
London
was
indeed
the
major destination
of
southern migrants. Hunt (1973: 281-2)
concludes that
"a
large part
of the
southern labor force appears
to
have operated
in a
particularly restricted market. They moved overwhelmingly
in one
direction
-
towards
London."
10
A
negative correlation between distance from London
and
relief expenditures
or
wage
income might
be
explained
by
regional differences
in the
cost
of
living rather than
by my
hypothesized cost-of-migration effect.
In
other words, real wage income
and per
capita
relief expenditures might
not
have varied inversely with distance from London even
though nominal wage income
and
relief expenditures did. Unfortunately, there
are
little
available data with which
to
test this hypothesis.
The
only attempt
to
measure regional
variations
in the
cost
of
living
has
been
by N. F. R.
Crafts (1982)
for the
year
1843. He
found that although
the
cost
of
living
was
indeed higher
in
London than
in the
rural
south, there
was no
evidence
of an
inverse relationship between cost
of
living
and
distance from London (1982:
62). One can
question this result, since Crafts assumes that
rural rents were equal throughout England (1982:
61).
However,
his
assumption
is
supported
by
evidence cited
in
Hunt (1973: 79-80).
In
order
to
take account
of the
regional cost-of-living differences found
by
Crafts,
I
deflated nominal wage income
and
per capita relief expenditures using
his
"rural perspective" southern agricultural price
index (1982:
62).