
96 An Economic History of the
English Poor
Law
ers were the wealthiest occupiers in most agricultural parishes.
14
Their
contribution to the poor rate can be estimated by assuming that all
ratepayers with property values larger than some amount x were labor-
hiring farmers, and all ratepayers with property values smaller than or
equal to x did not hire labor. To distinguish between labor-hiring farmers
and "family" farmers, x should be set equal to the typical rateable value of
the largest amount of land that could be farmed without hired labor.
15
Estimates of the amount of land a family could farm without hired labor
vary from
30
to
50
acres (Clapham
1930:
451;
Chambers and Mingay 1966:
133-4).
16
The rateable value of an acre of land was determined by the
parish; the typical rateable value seems to have been between 14s. and £1
per acre.
17
The above numbers yield a range of estimates for the maxi-
mum rateable value of
a
family farm of
£21
to
£50.
Table 3.3 contains data
on the share of the poor rate paid by taxpayers with rateable property
valued at or below
£25,
£30,
and
£40,
for
62
parishes in Cambridge, Essex,
and Suffolk. Assuming these are reasonable values for x, the average
share of the poor rate paid by non-labor-hiring taxpayers (labor-hiring
farmers) was 17.2-25.2% (74.8-82.8%).
The estimates in Table 3.3 may overstate the effective share of the
poor rate paid by labor-hiring farmers. Most farmers were tenants rather
than landowners. McCloskey
(1973:
423) maintained that because farm-
ers were mobile and land was not, "landlords in a parish with high poor
rates . . . would have to charge lower rents to attract farmers with alter-
native employment for their capital in parishes with low poor rates or
elsewhere in the economy."
18
There is evidence in the 1834 Poor Law
14
Recall that landowners who rented out their land to tenant farmers did not pay poor
rates.
15
Because shopkeepers and tradespeople typically were assessed only on the value of the
"lands and tenements" they occupied, their rateable value usually was less than that of
the largest family farmers.
16
The 1851 census contains data on farm size and on the number of hired laborers per
farmer. In England and Wales there were 97,800 (82,701) farms of 40 (30) acres or
smaller; 91,698 farmers hired no labor. This suggests that the amount of land that could
be farmed without hired labor was between 30 and 40 acres.
17
1 was able to locate assessments for only two Essex parishes: Pebmarsh (in 1838), and
Little Baddow (in 1827). In Pebmarsh, the total rateable value of 1,978 acres of land was
£1,911,
or 19.3s. per acre (Essex Record Office: D/P 207/11/6). In Little Baddow, arable
land was assessed at 5s.-20s. per acre, depending on its quality; most arable land,
however, was assessed at 14s.-20s. per acre. Pasture land was assessed at 14s.-28s. per
acre (Essex Record Office: D/P 35/11/3).
18
On the other hand, Blaug
(1963:
175) concluded that "it is far from obvious that rents
were in fact reduced when the rates rose. . . . [Ljeases of seven to fourteen years were
not uncommon, and those must have been very insensitive to increased overhead costs
incurred by tenants."