348 11. Risk Capital
losses certainly are bigger. In the intermediate stages of Basel II consulta-
tion, this effect was caught by a “granularity adjustment factor”. This factor,
however, was dropped later on during the political negotiations.
The next important message which emerges from the limit R → 0isthat
counterparty default correlation is the main driving factor of unexpected
losses in a sufficiently granular loan portfolio. Intuitively, this is easy to un-
derstand. With large default correlation, the number of independent loans is
reduced considerably, the portfolio effectively behaves as one with a few very
large loans, and fluctuations become appreciable.
In principle, the correlation coefficient R should be measured in a port-
folio, or for the entire banking book. Instead, in Basel II, it is fixed to the
value implied by (11.13) by the regulators. It decreases from 0.24 to 0.12
as PD increases from zero to one. The value R = 0 used in our argument,
is not permissible in Basel II! While the interpolation proposed certainly is
largly guesswork, the important message is that the default correlation of
very good loans is higher than that of badly rated loans. A simple-minded
picture where risky loans are likely to default due to obligor-specific factors,
e.g. bad management, but rather riskless loans would default mainly as a
collective phenomenon, e.g. due to economic downturn, is consistent with the
trend contained in (11.13).
Next, set the maturity, (11.15), M = 1. For a moment, ignore the exact
definition of M as a cash-flow averaged maturity, and think about it simply as
the lifetime of a loan. For M = 1, the maturity adjustment factor in (11.10)
reduces to unity, i.e. the Basel II capital charge has been calibrated on a
one-year lifetime of a loan (portfolio). It turns out that for a given one-year
default probability, the unexpected losses of a portfolio depend on its effective
maturity. The higher the maturity, i.e. the longer the lifetime of the loans,
the bigger the unexpected losses, i.e. the default risk. More capital thus is
required. However, the squared logarithmic dependence on default probability
and the five-digit figures in the maturity adjustment factor (11.15) certainly
are not to be taken too serious from a scientific point of view.
The regulatory capital requirement (11.10) is linear in the remaining open
parameters, EAD and LGD. The exposure at default, EAD, is the total
amount of loan outstanding at the time of default. Notice that even the
definition of “default” is not unique in banking. The standard is a “90 days
past due”-rule, i.e. the debtor is past due more than 90 days on a major
credit obligation. The sum of all payments outstanding and expected until
the maturity of the loan then is the exposure at default. EAD is measured in
real currency, e.g. dollars.
LGD is the loss given default. It is less than EAD because usually, the
bank is able to utilize collateral or other receivables, leading to a recovery.
LGD is measured as a fraction.
In the advanced IRB Approach, banks may estimate internally all three
open parameters of (11.10), PD, LGD, and EAD. M can be calculated from