GOVERNMENT AND THE ECONOMY IOI
From 1913 through 1922, gross revenue from the salt gabelle exceeded
gross maritime customs revenue. After 1922, however, only a part of the
income from salt was available to the central government. In order to
furnish security for the Reorganization Loan of 1913, without which the
government of Yuan Shih-k'ai might not have survived, a foreign chief
inspector was appointed to supervise and in effect control the Salt Admin-
istration. While national pride might be hurt, this measure resulted in an
immediate jump in the revenues collected on the account of the central
government. Actual payments on foreign loans secured on the salt
revenues were small - from 1917 the Reorganization Loan, for example,
was paid from the customs revenue. But this relatively happy situation
was swept away by the continuous civil warfare. Provincial interference
in the salt tax collection grew to serious proportions, salt funds were mis-
appropriated, and smuggling increased. Total revenue fell markedly
after 1922, as did the proportion of the collection that was actually
remitted to Peking. Net collections, which had hit a peak of Ch.$86
million in 1922, fell to Ch.$7i million in 1924, Ch.$64 million in 1926,
and down to Ch.$j8 million in 1927. Even in 1922 only Ch.$47 million
(or
5 5
per cent of the net collection) was actually remitted to Peking;
Ch.$i2 million was retained by the provinces with the central govern-
ment's consent; but Ch.$2o million (23 per cent) was appropriated locally
without consent. The total amount retained by provincial authorities and
military commanders climbed to Ch.$37 million in 1926 while the amount
actually remitted to Peking in that year was barely Ch.$9 million.
104
Faced with a chronic state of financial embarrassment, the Peking
government was forced to depend heavily on domestic and foreign
borrowing. Between 1912 and 1926, 27 domestic bond issues were floated
by the Ministry of Finance with a combined face value of Ch.S
614,000,000.
IO!
Actual receipts to the government, however, were consid-
erably smaller, for the bonds were always sold at a discount - in an
extreme case as low as 20 per cent of the face value. Much is obscure
about the details of domestic loan notations in this period, and on into
the period of the Nanking government as well. There seems to have been
a close relationship between the establishment of new banks with the
right of note issue and government domestic borrowing. A large part of
these domestic bonds was taken up by the Chinese 'modern' banks who
held government securities as investment and as reserves against note
issue, while also making direct advances to the government.
104 P. T. Chen, 'Public finance', The Chinese year book, I9)f-i9)i, 1298-9.
105 Ch'ien Chia-chii, Chiu Chung-kuo kung-thai shih tzu-liao, 1S94-1949 (Source materials on
government bond issues in old China, 1894-1949), 566-9.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008