80 ECONOMIC TRENDS, 1912-49
Research Bureau's investigators for the 'average' value of
a mou
of land in
Shantung.
6
'
Estimates of the extent of tenancy in republican China vary considera-
bly, and of course local differences were enormous, but overall about 50
per cent
of
the peasantry were involved
in
the landlord-tenant relation-
ship
-
about 30 per cent as tenants who rented all of the land that they
farmed, and 20 per cent more as owner-tenants who rented part of their
land. Table 16(1) presents two estimates
of
the rates of tenancy by pro-
vince
in
the 1930s, which, although they differ in detail, clearly indicate
the much greater incidence of pure tenancy in the rice-growing provinces
of the Yangtze valley and the southern coast than in the wheat-growing
north.
70
These provincial data often obscure very considerable local
variations within any province resulting from location, land quality,
degree of commercialization and historical accretions.
7
'
It
should also be
noted that the categories owner, owner-tenant and tenant do not neces-
sarily represent a descending order of economic well-being. The somewhat
more complex categorization of the National Land Commission's 1934-5
survey shown in table
17,
for example, is a warning that the rubric 'owner-
tenant'
in
table 16(1) subsumes every case from
a
landlord who rents
1
per cent
of
his land
to
a poor peasant who rents 95 per cent. And the
farmers
of
Shansi, Shantung, Hopei and Honan with less population
pressure and larger farms, who were predominantly owner-cultivators,
were not better off with respect to family income than their tenant brethren
in Kwangtung. Nor
is
tenancy incompatible with economic progress:
note that in the United States the percentage of farm operators who were
tenants increased from 25.6 per cent in 1879 to 34.5 per cent in 1945.
Reliable historical data on the changing incidence of tenancy are nearly
non-existent. A comparison of the estimates compiled by local observers,
missionaries and others
in
the 1880s with those for the 1930s suggests
considerable variation by locality but no significant change in the overall
tenancy rate.
72
National Agricultural Bureau estimates show only a slight
69 National government, Directorate
of
Statistics, Chung-hua min-kuo t'ung-chi t'i-yao,
/f)j
(Statistical abstract of the Republic of China, 1935),
462-3,
shows land values in Shantung
in 1933 as roughly the same as those in Chekiang; the NARB 1934 Shantung value, how-
ever,
is
one-third lower than Chekiang.
70 In table 16(1)
I
have used Buck's alternative estimate derived from his 'agricultural survey'
rather than his 'farm survey' percentages which are usually cited. The latter are obviously
too low both because his sample gives inadequate weight
to
the southern provinces, and
because the nature of the survey dictated that relatively accessible localities dominated the
data.
71 For regional variations
in
Kiangsu, see Ash, Land
tenure
in
pre-revoiutionary
China, 11-22;
for Shantung and Hopei, Myers, The
Chinese
economy,
234-40.
72 George Jamieson, 'Tenure of land
in
China and the condition
of
the rural population',
Journal of
the
North China
Branch
of
the
Royal Asiatic
Society,
23 (1889) 59-117.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008