Political economy
friend Harriet Martineau (Illustrations of Taxation, Poor Laws and Paupers
Illustrated, Letters on Mesmerism) was similarly prolific; even by late in the
century, political economy was a subject for women writers, including
Margaret Benson (Capital, Labour and Trade) and Millicent Fawcett (Tales
in Political Economy). Richard Ely found German historicism (or German
social theory-cum-social policy) so exhilarating, he recalled, because the
only economic instruction for undergraduates at Columbia University in
the 1870s had consisted of weekly recitations from ‘Mrs. Fawcett’s “Political
Economy for Beginners”’ (Ely 1910,p.70).
The statistical idiom of writing on social reform constituted a different
model of intermediate thought, or of the diffusion of ideas. The historical
school of Gustav Schmoller’s associations and yearbooks and bureaux was
unified, if at all, by the use of statistics, and by a political rhetoric which
sought to convince with numbers (see Grimmer-Solem 2003). In England,
social reform was itself a distinctively feminine subject. The French histo-
rian and psychologist Hippolyte Taine observed that psychology, statistics
and political economy were proceeding together in England, and that the
‘social sciences’ were substantially a concern of women; he mentioned
Louisa Twining, Barbara Collett, Mary Carpenter, Florence Hill, Florence
Nightingale, Bessie Parkes, Sarah Remond, ‘Mistress Wiggins’ and Jane
Crowe (Taine 1872,pp.99, 338). For Alfred Marshall, it was rather ‘gen-
eral economic principles’ of a ‘dictatorial sort’, which were associated with
women writers; ‘never again will a Mrs Trimmer, a Mrs Marcet, or a Miss
Martineau earn a goodly reputation by throwing them into the form of a
catechism or of simple tales’ (Marshall 1897,p.117).
The diffusion of economic ideas was important, above all, to the rise, over
the entire course of the century, of large-scale political movements. The
nineteenth century was an age of ‘-isms’: Philoguillotismus, Demokratismus
and Antirevolutionairrismus, as the historian Bartold Niebuhr complained in
the 1790s; Obscurantismus, Enthusiasmus, Sophisticismus, Fanatismus,andEgo-
ismus, according to a work of 1802 about enlightenment and revolution
(Niebuhr 1926, i,pp.7, 32, 35, 37; Salat 1802,pp.162, 187, 193). These
were abstract nouns which identified political or religious opinions. But
the most successful abstractions of the later nineteenth century identified
(or collected together) economic opinions. Like the religious ideolog ies or
‘-isms’, they had a connotation of Catechismus, and its etymology of oral
instruction, or of resonance and downwardness. This process of instruction
in turn required the simplification of complicated ideas into single con-
cepts. It was a process, too, which required extensive material resources;
775