Political economy
the level of subsistence (Malthus 1826, ii,pp.4, 42, 337, 347). The ‘mon-
ster Malthus’ and his followers were the theorists, in the journalist William
Cobbett’s description, of the ‘unfeeling oligarchs and their toad-eaters’, or
of ‘a grinding, an omnipresent, never-sleeping oligarchy of money’ (Cobbett
1830,p.356, 1831, ii,no.5,p.119).
The political economists were inculpated, eventually, in what was
described as an awesome enterprise of moral and spiritual destruction. The
study of political economy, William Godwin wrote in 1820, was considered
to be responsible for ‘the heart of flint that has disgraced the beginning
of the nineteenth century’ (Godwin 1820,p.112). The critique was in a
part a continuation of the polemics of the early years of the century; the
denunciation of the economists for their disrespectful view of the state, and
of the state’s responsibility for religious and moral improvement. But it also
turned, more insidiously, on a conflict of conceptions of human nature.
The poet Robert Southey described Smith as a Diogenes of the modern
employee, poised to ‘pluck the wings of his intellect, strip him of the down
and plumage of his virtues, and behold in the brute, denuded, pitiable
animal, the man of the manufacturing system!’ (Southey 1812,p.337).
The effect of materialist doctrines, the French Catholic theorist F
´
elicit
´
e
de Lamennais wrote in 1820, was to transform society into an anarchy of
interests and desires. The new economic society would be a universalisation
of England; a country that was dead because of its morality or mentality, a
corpse galvanised only by the convulsions of cupidity, or by ‘an unquiet and
prodigious activity, which some take to be life, and which is life, as fever is
life, as the contractions of a galvanism are life’ (Lamennais 1820, i,pp.74,
375).
The tendency of political economy, on this view, was to destroy the moral
foundations of social existence and individual virtue. The economists were
criticised for being cold and hard-hearted in the policies they proposed, and
for having a dismal view of the future of society. They were criticised, too,
for their dismal view of the nature of men in general, and of the working
classes in particular: ‘inert, sluggish, and averse from labour’, and induced
by vice into ‘inextricable unhappiness’, in Malthus’ description of 1798;
or stimulated by the desire for money, with ‘self-love for the mainspring
of the great machine’ (Malthus 1798,pp.70, 207, 363). The consequence
of all this coldness, in turn, was even more sinister. The economists were
putting forward a description of society, and in the view of their critics,
they were at the same time changing societies, and changing individual
dispositions.
757