Emma Rothschild
to depict the ‘full empirical reality’ of economic life (Grimmer-Solem and
Romani 1999). Economists associated with the multiple historical schools,
from Germany, Hungary, Ireland and England to India, Japan and the United
States, were actively involved in the invention of local, regional, national
and international statistical offices, and in the collection and dissemination
of statistical information (see Grimmer-Solem 2003 and Studenski 1958).
The duty of both ‘historical’ and ‘orthodox’ economists was no longer, in
Beatrice Webb’s description, to lecture ‘politicians on the worn out text
of laisser-faire’, and to ‘imagine themselves to be the schoolmasters of the
universe’. It was rather to provide scientific advice on factory legislation,
employer’s liability acts, compulsory registration of friendly societies, mer-
chant shipping bills, ‘Charity commissions, Societies for the prevention of
the enclosure of commons &c., &c’ (Webb 1886, 3: 35, 37, 52).
The idioms of statistical reasoning were common, by the late nineteenth
century, to Germans and English, free-traders and protectionists. Even James
Wilson, the founder of The Economist, had very little taste for the ‘more
refined abstractions’ of the ‘more specially scientific Political Economists’.
He had ‘what may be called a business-imagination’, his son-in-law, Walter
Bagehot, wrote in 1860; ‘he had a great power of conceiving transactions’.
Wilson had founded The Economist in 1843, as a ‘weekly Free Trader’. It
became profitable, influential and widely imitated; it included a ‘bankers’
gazette’, a ‘railway monitor’, and copious statistical information; ‘the best
shape of communicating information had to be invented in detail’, in Bage-
hot’s account. It employed a redoubtable collection of journalists, many of
them with connections to other economic media, including Bagehot him-
self, Herbert Spencer, who was sub-editor from 1848 to 1853, and R. H. I.
Palgrave, later of Palgrave’s Dictionary of Political Economy.ButThe Economist
was also a new kind of medium between economic doctrines and a public
opinion, English and worldwide, which was transfixed by economic news,
economic statistics and economic ‘questions’, ideologies, or ‘-isms’. ‘He was
agreatbelief producer’, Bagehot wrote of Wilson; he diffused the truths, or
the ideas, which were ‘“in the air” of the age’ (Bagehot 1860,pp.1289–91,
1293; Edwards 1993,pp.4, 15, 143–51).
4 Abstract and deductive ideas
The ‘belief in the Historical Method’ was by the 1880s ‘the most widely and
strongly entertained philosophical conviction at the present day’ (Sidgwick
1886,p.203). But the moment of triumph of historical-statistical political
764