The incoming and outgoing variables are referred to as the independent and dependent vari-
ables respectively. The value of y clearly ‘depends’ on the actual value of x that is fed into the
function. For example, in microeconomics the quantity demanded, Q, of a good depends on
the market price, P. We might express this as
Q = f(P)
Such a function is called a demand function. Given any particular formula for f(P) it is then a
simple matter to produce a picture of the corresponding demand curve on graph paper. There
is, however, a difference of opinion between mathematicians and economists on how this
should be done. If your quantitative methods lecturer is a mathematician then he or she is likely
to plot Q on the vertical axis and P on the horizontal axis. Economists, on the other hand, norm-
ally plot them the other way round with Q on the horizontal axis. In doing so, we are merely
noting that since Q is related to P then, conversely, P must be related to Q, and so there is a
function of the form
P = g(Q)
The two functions, f and g, are said to be inverse functions: that is, f is the inverse of g and,
equivalently, g is the inverse of f. We adopt the economists’ approach in this book. In sub-
sequent chapters we shall investigate other microeconomic functions such as total revenue,
average cost, and profit. It is conventional to plot each of these against Q (that is, with Q on the
horizontal axis), so it makes sense to be consistent and to do the same here.
Written in the form P = g(Q), the demand function tells us that P is a function of Q but it
gives us no information about the precise relationship between these two variables. To find this
we need to know the form of the function which can be obtained either from economic theory
or from empirical evidence. For the moment we hypothesize that the function is linear so that
P = aQ + b
for some appropriate constants (called parameters), a and b. Of course, in reality, the relation-
ship between price and quantity is likely to be much more complicated than this. However, the
use of linear functions makes the mathematics nice and easy, and the result of any analysis at least
provides a first approximation to the truth. The process of identifying the key features of the real
world and making appropriate simplifications and assumptions is known as modelling. Models
are based on economic laws and help to explain and predict the behaviour of real-world situ-
ations. Inevitably there is a conflict between mathematical ease and the model’s accuracy.
The closer the model comes to reality, the more complicated the mathematics is likely to be.
A graph of a typical linear demand function is shown in Figure 1.14 (overleaf). Elementary
theory shows that demand usually falls as the price of a good rises and so the slope of the line
is negative. Mathematically, P is then said to be a decreasing function of Q.
1.3 • Supply and demand analysis
49
Practice Problem
1 Evaluate
(a)
f(25) (b) f(1) (c) f(17) (d) g(0) (e) g(48) (f) g(16)
for the two functions
f(x) =−2x + 50
g(x) =−
1
/2 x + 25
Do you notice any connection between f and g?
MFE_C01c.qxd 16/12/2005 10:56 Page 49