
system in particular. In order to cut labour costs large Japanese companies have shed an
increasing amount of their labour force. Well-known examples are Nissan, which has
closed five car plants and shed 21,000 jobs to stave off bankruptcy; Nippon Steel, which
shed 40 per cent of its 10,000 white-collar workers between 1993 and 1997; Sony, which
got rid of 17,000 jobs; and NEC which disposed of 15,000.
15
Such dramatic cuts explain
the plethora of articles in the popular business press that predict the demise of lifetime
employment.
However, the fact that the Japanese lifetime employment system has always been
limited to a small proportion of the workforce, combined with the diversity of practices
that have always been used by Japanese corporations to cut labour costs in times of dis-
tress, demands caution when examining, and making bold statements about so-called
dramatic changes to the system. In general, a lot of Japanese firms still tend to rely on tra-
ditional responses to negative situations (Tanisaka and Ohtake, 2003). These include a
reduction in working hours and overtime payment for currently employed full-time core
workers; an increase in ‘service overtime’ (overtime without pay); less employment for
new graduates; and an increase in shukko (temporary transfers between firms) and tenseki
(transfers to another company, or change of long-term employment), both of which effec-
tively reallocate workers within the internal labour market (Mroczkowski and Hanaoka,
1997; Sato, 1999; Fujiki et al., 2001; Genda, 2003). Moreover, many of the current job
cuts are argued to have been designed to minimize job losses in Japan and to maximize
those elsewhere; some of them are said to be part of early-retirement programmes;
16
and
others affect the peripheral rather than the core workforce.
17
Moreover, labour shedding via dismissals and calls for voluntary retirement, which
happens increasingly during the ongoing recession, is still considered the very last resort
for Japanese firms in streamlining their structures, and to be a measure that only these
firms in critical condition would resort to (Tanisaka and Ohtake, 2003). Indeed, while
most Japanese firms have adopted a mandatory retirement system with the age of 60 as
the common retirement age, the system at the same time functions to secure employment
for full-time regular workers until the mandatory retirement age (Sato, 1999). It seems
more appropriate, then, to see the new conditions of employment as modifications of the
lifetime employment system, not a contradiction of it (Kono and Clegg, 2001). Until now,
the basic structure of the Japanese employment system has remained intact. Lifetime
employment of the core is retained – not only because it is a protected right, but also
because of the heightened dependence on stable and predictable relationships with labour
at the plant level, in the context of tightly coupled production networks and the demands
of producing at high quality on a just-in-time basis.
Similarly, while a few major Japanese employers have made the choice to modify the
rules regarding seniority-based pay and promotion,
18
this is far from being a modal prac-
tice. In the early 1990s, the recession and the emphasis on the creation of new
GLOBALIZATION, CONVERGENCE AND SOCIETAL SPECIFICITY 539
15
Economist, 9 October 1997, ‘On a roll’; 18 November 1999, ‘The worm turns’; 23 August 2001, ‘An alterna-
tive to cocker spaniels’.
16
Japan Labor Bulletin, September 2003, 4.
17
Economist, 9 October 1997, ‘On a roll’; 23 August 2001, ‘An alternative to cocker spaniels’.
18
In 1999, Matsushita changed its seniority-based wage system for its 11,000 managers. This behaviour was
followed by some other big companies; i.e. by Fujitsu, Fuji Xerox, Asahi Glass, Asahi Breweries, Kansai Electric and
Itochu Corporation (Economist, 20 May 1999, ‘Putting the bounce back into Matsushita’).
MG9353 ch12.qxp 10/3/05 8:49 am Page 539