Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
P1: GDZ
0521812909c07 CB929-Bulmer 0 521 81290 9 October 6, 2005 12:28
260 Richard Salvucci
a consideration that should be underestimated – explain why Latin Amer-
ica under the gold standard might as fairly be termed Latin America “on
and off ” the gold standard. For, if nothing, else, as Keynes pointed out,
the system of fixed exchange rates efficiently transmitted economic crises
between countries, a dubious benefit for peripheral economies rendered
more, rather than less, stable by the monetary regime.
The principal implication of this discussion is the difficulty of consistent
long-term growth from peripheral countries under the gold standard. If,
in fact, macroeconomic stability were not a strong point of the system,
the ability of the Latin American economies to provide adequate levels
of income and satisfactory rates of growth would be quite questionable.
As Victor Bulmer-Thomas has pointed out, the main reason why income
levels there in the twentieth century are well behind those of the devel-
oped countries in general, not to mention the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) members (Mexico excluded, of
course), is because consistent, long-term performance is virtually impossi-
ble to find. Volatility, in other words, is as much a cause as a consequence
of “underdevelopment,” and it is difficult to see how the currency regime
described by Alec Ford and others could have done anything other than
amplify domestic volatility, the intrinsic variability of commodity prices
aside. In this regard, as we shall see, the growth experienced by Colombia,
Mexico, and Peru, and by Central America on silver through the mid-1890s,
may well suggest merit to the continuing depreciation of the exchange rate
that the international fall in silver prices brought after 1872.
Recent studies of Brazil and Chile have amplified, augmented, and
extended these findings. Brazil, for instance, was able to adopt the gold
standard when ample capital imports allowed it to do so, but remaining
there proved difficult. The domestic fluctuations in macroeconomic activ-
ity described by Ford occurred with an appreciating exchange rate (which
raised opposition from coffee exporters); rising imports; a deteriorating
balance of payments; and, inevitably, pressure to suspend convertibility
altogether. The gold standardbrought price rather than macroeconomic sta-
bility to Brazil, historians of its operation have concluded. Chile was able to
remain on the gold standard only for brief periods of time (1870–8, 1895–8),
buffeted as it was by large fluctuations in copper and nitrate exports.
Moreover, wages and prices in Chile proved highly inflexible, which
made the country an unlikely candidate for a fixed exchange rate, given
that a decline in external demand required deflation, which was diffi-
cult to achieve. Chile benefited from a floating exchange rate between