(Nihon), which he contends at best enjoyed limited and contested use during the
premodern period.
9
Overall, Amino’s scholarship works to decenter our understanding of the origins of
what eventually became the modern Japanese nation-state. In searching for new
origins and elevating the importance of diverse historical actors, his arguments
necessarily raise doubts about the legitimacy of the modern imperial institution and
the necessity of sacrifices made in the name of sanctity which he finds entirely
specious. While demoting the historical significance of a single central imperial
order, Amino endorses the importance of Japan as being composed of variou s
autonomous or semi-autonomous zones in coastal regions and mountain settlements.
Within these zones, some of them frontiers, people worked in a variety of callings, not
just as peasant farmers, but also as fisherfolk, traders, potters, and silk weavers.
One of the most important arguments Amino makes on the basis of lively pre-
modern non-farming economic activity is that capitalism developed far earlier in this
decentralized order than has been previously understood. H e demonstrates its ap-
pearance in studies of medieval temple moneylenders, the use of monetary instru-
ments in financial transactions, and payment of taxes in commodities other than
grain. He concludes that as early as the fourteenth century regions within Japan
had already experienced ‘‘growth in commerce, industry, finance, and shipping, the
close-knit development of a distribution system necessary for supporting a stable
credit economy, and thriving trade and other contacts ranging from northern East
Asia all the way down to Southeast Asia.’’
10
Amino’s work on contentious regional
relations between different groups within Japan, which he associates with the exist-
ence of a basic east–west divide, argues for variable political and economic centers
with their own or shared peripheries . As he makes plain in his discussion of the rise
and decline of the Nara–Kyoto-based imperial order, Japan’s history has not been a
unidirectional march toward ever greater political and economic centralization, but
one of twists and turns and even backtracking as regional fortunes changed over time.
Amino has been joined by other historians in Japan who, if less absolute in their
revision of premodern center–periphery relations, endorse his doubts about the
state’s unified origins. They also tend to view Japan’s heterogeneous past as a
construct repeatedly contested and remade before it became ‘‘Japanese history’’ in
relatively modern times. Murai Sho
¯
suke is rep resentative in viewing the borders of
medieval Japan as existing less as hard and fast lines than as zones which, accordion-
like, expanded and contracted. Following Amino, he de-emphasizes the agrarian
basis of premodern Japan in highlighting the importance of trade relations at frontier
zones. These ties involved economic exchange and indicated places where ethnical ly
identical people engaged in ‘‘foreign’’ trade within the space now known as Japan.
At the same time, other groups in coastal ports and harbors partici pated in exchanges
that were almost ‘‘domestic’’ even though they engaged ethnically different
partners from across the China Sea, the Sea of Japan, and from the Ryu
¯
kyu
¯
s and
Hokkaido
¯
.
11
Bruce Batten has expanded on the decentering work of Amino, Murai, and others
by applying various social science theories across far wider time frames. In To the Ends
of Japan: Premodern Frontiers, Boundaries, and Interactions he explicitly poses ‘‘big
questions’’ such as ‘‘What is ‘Japan’?’’ ‘‘When did it come to be?’’ ‘‘How did it
change over time?’’ and ‘‘How does it fit into the larger world?’’ His attempts to
CENTER AND PERIPHERY 427