264 Chapter 11 Reproducible Private Proprety Resources: Agriculture and Food Security
In contrast, he argues, lifeboat ethics would suggest a better resolution of the
dilemma; the 50 or 60 should row away, leaving the others to certain death, but
saving those fortunate enough to gain entry into the lifeboat. The implication is that
food sharing is counterproductive. It would encourage more population growth and
ultimately would cause inevitable, even more serious shortages in the future.
The existence of a global scarcity of food is the premise that underlies this view;
when famine is inevitable, sharing is merely a palliative and may, in the long run,
even become counterproductive. In the absence of global scarcity (the lifeboat has
a large enough capacity for all) then, a worldwide famine can be avoided by a
sharing of resources. How accurate is the global scarcity premise?
Formulating the Global Scarcity Hypothesis
Most authorities seem to agree that an adequate amount of food is currently being
produced. Because the evidence is limited to a single point in time, however, it
provides little sense of whether scarcity is decreasing or increasing. If we are to
identify and evaluate trends, we must develop more precise, measurable notions of
how the market allocates food.
As a renewable resource, cereal grains could be produced indefinitely, if managed
correctly. Yet two facets of the world hunger problem have to be taken into account.
First, while population growth has slowed down, it has not stopped. Therefore, it is
reasonable to expect the rising demand for food to continue. Second, the primary
input for growing food is land, and land is ultimately fixed in supply. Thus, our
analysis must explain how a market reacts in the presence of rising demand for a
renewable resource that is produced using a fixed factor of production.
A substantial and dominant proportion of the Western world’s arable land is
privately owned. Access to this land is restricted; therefore the owners have the
right to exclude others and can reap what they sow. The typical owner of farmland
has sufficient control over the resource to prevent undue depreciation, but not
enough control over the market as a whole to raise the specter of monopoly profits.
What kind of outcome could we expect from this market in the face of rising
demand and a fixed supply of land? What do we mean by scarcity and how could we
perceive its existence? The answer depends crucially on the height and slope of the
supply curve for food (see Figure 11.1).
Suppose the market is initially in equilibrium with quantity Q
0
supplied at price
P
0
. Let the passage of time be recorded as outward shifts in the demand curve.
Consider what would happen in the fifth time period. If the supply curve were S
a
,
the quantity would rise to Q
5a
with a price of P
5a
. However, if the supply curve were
S
b
, the quantity supplied would rise to Q
5b
, but price would rise to P
5b
.
This analysis sheds light on two dimensions of scarcity in the world food
market. It normally does not mean a shortage. Even under relatively adverse
supply circumstances pictured by the supply curve S
b
, the amount of food supplied
would equal the amount demanded. As prices rose, potential demand would be
choked off and additional supplies would be called forth.