62 Chapter 3 Evaluating Trade-Offs: Benefit–Cost Analysis and Other Decision-Making Metrics
4
http://yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eed.nsf/webpages/Guidelines.html/$file/Guidelines.pdf
5
Annual rates can be found at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/. 2010 rates can be found at http://
www.whitehouse.gov/omb/circulars_a094/a94_appx-c.
on disadvantaged groups or sub-populations. The latter delves into the normative
issue of equity or fairness in the distribution of costs and benefits. The issue of
environmental justice will be considered further in Chapter 19.
4
Loomis (2011)
outlines several approaches for incorporating distribution and equity into
benefit–cost analysis.
Choosing the Discount Rate
The discount rate can be defined conceptually as the social opportunity cost of capital.
This cost of capital can be divided further into two components: (1) the riskless cost of
capital and (2) the risk premium. The choice of the discount rate can influence policy
decisions. Recall that discounting allows us to compare all costs and benefits in current
dollars, regardless of when the benefits accrue or costs are charged. Suppose, a project
will impose an immediate cost of $4,000,000 (today’s dollars), but the $5,500,000 ben-
efits will not be earned until 5 years out. Is this project a good idea? On the surface it
might seem like it is, but recall that $5,500,000 in 5 years is not the same as $5,500,000
today. At a discount rate of 5 percent, the present value of benefits minus the present
value of costs is positive. However, at a 10 percent discount rate, this same calculation
yields a negative value, since the present value of costs exceeds the benefits. Can you
reproduce the calculations that yield these conclusions?
As Example 3.4 indicates, this has been, and continues to be, an important issue.
When the public sector uses a discount rate lower than that in the private sector, the
public sector will find more projects with longer payoff periods worthy of
authorization. And, as we have already seen, the discount rate is a major determinant
of the allocation of resources among generations as well.
Traditionally, economists have used long-term interest rates on government
bonds as one measure of the cost of capital, adjusted by a risk premium that would
depend on the riskiness of the project considered. Unfortunately, the choice of how
large an adjustment to make has been left to the discretion of the analysts. This
ability to affect the desirability of a particular project or policy by the choice of
discount rate led to a situation in which government agencies were using a variety
of discount rates to justify programs or projects they supported. One set of hearings
conducted by Congress during the 1960s discovered that, at one time, agencies
were using discount rates ranging from 0 to 20 percent.
During the early 1970s the Office of Management and Budget published a
circular that required, with some exceptions, all government agencies to use a
discount rate of 10 percent in their benefit–cost analysis. A revision issued in 1992
reduced the required discount rate to 7 percent. This circular also includes guide-
lines for benefit–cost analysis and specifies that certain rates will change annually.
5
This standardization reduces biases by eliminating the agency’s ability to choose a
discount rate that justifies a predetermined conclusion. It also allows a project to be