PFE Chapter 24: Facts about option prices page 8
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
ABC
Microsoft stock price, 15 August 2001, S
0
63
Option exercise price, X 60
Option exercise time, T (in years) 1
Interest rate, r 10%
Call price at time 0 (today) 5
Below examine if this price
<-- violates the arbitrage restriction
Actions at time 0 (today)
Short the stock 63 <-- =B2
Buy a bond which pays of X at time T -54.55 <-- =-B3/(1+B5)^B4
Buy a call -5 <-- =-B7
Total cash flow at time 0
3.45 <-- =SUM(B11:B13)
Cash flow at time T
S
T
, stock price at time T
90
Repay the shorted stock -90 <-- =-B17
Collect money from the bond 60 <-- =B3
Exercise the call? 30 <-- =MAX(B17-B3,0)
Total cash flow at time T
0 <-- =SUM(B19:B21)
ARBITRAGE PROOF OF FACT 1
ARBITRAGE STRATEGY
By changing the stock price
S
T
, you can see that our strategy always produces no worse
than a zero cash flow at time
T. This makes it an arbitrage strategy:
• At time 0, the cash flow is $3.45 > 0
• At time T, the cash flow is either positive (if the stock price S
T
< 60) or zero.
You can’t lose from this strategy!! In a rational world this means that something is wrong with
the asset prices. In this case, it’s clear what’s wrong—the call price is too low.
To see this, consider the case where the call price is $10. As you can see below (cell
B14), this means that the initial cash flow from the arbitrage strategy is negative. If the stock
price at time
T is less than $60, say S
T
= $55, then you will make a future profit (cell B22 below),
but this profit is no longer an arbitrage profit (recall that arbitrage occurs when you can
never
lose money—with a $10 call price, you start off with an initial negative cash flow):