GOODS
349
These
developments of industrial and financial
capital-
ism
have
produced consequences for which the early ex-
positors of
the system were evidently
unprepared.
Thus it
was
taken for granted
that "saving" and
"consumption"
were two
separate
processes
which did not
go on
side
by
side, but
one after the other. This looks plausible
to
the
individual who receives
$2,000
a
year, and knows that
if
he
saves
$500,
he
cuts
down his consumption
by
$500.
Harold
G.
Moulton, however, contends that
it
is unsound
to project this mode
of thought upon collective
processes.
Using the term
"capital"
to
cover
"implements,
tools, ma-
chines,
industrial buildings, railroad
tracks,
power houses,
and
other concrete material instruments which aid man
in
the
processes
of
production," he shows that periods
of
rapid capital formation, and periods of rapid increase
in
consumption, march side by side, not single file. This
means that the flow of funds to the
investment
market
does
not automatically increase the creation of capital equip-
ment. Moulton's analysis shows that savings which entered
the investment markets during the
prosperous
years
of the
twenties inflated the price
of securities rather
than pro-
moted a proportionate growth of plant and equipment.
And
it was the free creation of
credit
by the commercial
banks that made most
of
this possible.
Hence it is proposed
to
remodel the routines of
capi-
talistic economy
by
abolishing commercial banks
and
separating the deposit from the investment function. This
might
be done by
requiring
100 per cent reserve against
demand or
short-term
deposits.
Investing would
then rep-
resent "real saving." It is anticipated that the most
im-
portant source of instability would be
eliminated.
It is
not
yet plain what
combination
of vested
and sentimental
inter-
ests, aligned behind this
suggestion, would refrain
from
nullifying policies, such as the
direct inflation
of the cir-