
in the shade of istanbul and moscow (1671–1783) 215
in the 15th century.
593
While in the 16th century, the khans enjoyed
unrivalled charisma and power in comparison to Ottoman provincial
governors and even refused to be treated on equal footing with the
Ottoman grand viziers, in the 18th century the khan could be com-
pared merely with an Ottoman provincial governor, appointed and
revoked at will by the Porte. In fact, the Ottoman provincial governors
had oen more means and followers due to the lengthening of their
tenures and the ongoing decentralization in the Ottoman provincial
administration. e Polish situation was seemingly dierent from the
Crimean one with only four royal elections in the 18th century, yet
they all but one were secured by foreign troops. e sole exception
was the second election of Stanisław Leszczyński, and the abrupt end
of his reign proves that it was impossible to rule in Warsaw without
St. Petersburg’s consent.
594
593
See the appended table: Chronology of the reigns of Crimean khans, Polish
kings, and Lithuanian grand dukes (1386–1795); there were six accessions between
1441–1500, twelve between 1501–1600, nineteen between 1601–1700, and thirty in the
years 1701–1783; a number of rulers ascended the throne several times.
594
On the “absolutist oensive” launched from Stockholm, St. Petersburg, Istanbul,
Vienna, and Dresden against East European noble societies in the early 18th century,
see the brilliant and informed study by Orest Subtelny, Domination of Eastern Europe.
Native Nobilities and Foreign Absolutism, 1500–1715 (Kingston-Montreal-Gloucester,
1986), esp. pp. 52–59. e author juxtaposes more eective absolutist states, orga-
nized about the goal-oriented (power-oriented) organizational principle against the
“welfare associations” of the East European noble elites, based on an associative prin-
ciple. Although Subtelny does not include the Crimea in his analysis, focusing on
Poland-Lithuania, Hungary, Livonia, Moldavia, and Cossack Ukraine, the Crimean
Khanate, with its powerful nobility and the limits to the khan’s power, would per-
fectly t his model. Somewhat similar conclusions were drawn in the Marxist study
by Perry Anderson, who stressed the inevitability of absolutism as a “natural” stage in
state and social development characteristic for early modern Europe; see idem, Lin-
eages of the Absolutist State (London, 1974), esp. pp. 297–298 referring to the “Polish
anomaly.” Both quoted authors believe that the societies which “failed” to develop
domestic absolutisms were “punished” by absolutisms from abroad. Yet, their argu-
ments invoke some reservations: rstly, they both chose to ignore such cases as Eng-
land or the Netherlands, where the spectacular failures of absolutist tendencies did
not prevent state and social development (admittedly, Anderson refers to England
and his conclusion that “before it could reach the age of maturity, English Absolutism
was cut o by a bourgeois revolution” undercuts his very argument that absolutism
was a natural stage of development; cf. ibidem, p. 142); secondly, by assuming that
power is more important than welfare (admittedly, few elite members in early modern
European states—absolutist or not—cared about the peasants’ welfare), one should
draw the conclusion that today North Korea is ahead of France because it manages to
concentrate a far larger part of its GNP towards power.