In general, we want to optimize a function,
z = f(x, y)
called the objective function subject to a constraint
ϕ
(x, y) = M
Here
ϕ
, the Greek letter phi, is a known function of two variables and M is a known constant.
The problem is to pick the pair of numbers (x, y) which maximizes or minimizes f(x, y) as
before. This time, however, we limit the choice of pairs to those which satisfy
ϕ
(x, y) = M
A graphical interpretation should make this clear. To be specific, let us suppose that a firm
wants to maximize output and that the production function is of the form
Q = f(K, L)
Let the costs of each unit of capital and labour be P
K
and P
L
respectively. The cost to the firm
of using as input K units of capital and L units of labour is
P
K
K + P
L
L
so if the firm has a fixed amount, M, to spend on these inputs then
P
K
K + P
L
L = M
The problem is one of trying to maximize the objective function
Q = f(K, L)
subject to the cost constraint
P
K
K + P
L
L = M
Sketched in Figure 5.14 (overleaf) is a typical isoquant map. As usual, points on any one isoquant
yield the same level of output and as output rises the isoquants themselves move further away
from the origin. Also sketched in Figure 5.14 is the cost constraint. This is called an isocost
curve because it gives all combinations of K and L which can be bought for a fixed cost, M.
The fact that
P
K
K + P
L
L = M
is represented by a straight line should come as no surprise to you by now. We can even rewrite
it in the more familiar ‘y = ax + b’ form and so identify its slope and intercept. In Figure 5.14,
L is plotted on the horizontal axis and K is plotted on the vertical axis, so we need to rearrange
P
K
K + P
L
L = M
to express K in terms of L. Subtracting P
L
L from both sides and dividing through by P
K
gives
K =− L +
The isocost curve is therefore a straight line with slope −P
L
/P
K
and intercept M/P
K
. Graphically,
our constrained problem is to choose that point on the isocost line which maximizes output.
This is given by the point labelled A in Figure 5.14. Point A certainly lies on the isocost line and
it maximizes output because it also lies on the highest isoquant. Other points, such as B and C,
also satisfy the constraint but they lie on lower isoquants and so yield smaller levels of output
than A. Point A is characterized by the fact that the isocost line is tangential to an isoquant. In
other words, the slope of the isocost line is the same as that of the isoquant at A.
M
P
K
D
F
P
L
P
K
A
C
5.5 • Constrained optimization
401
MFE_C05e.qxd 16/12/2005 10:43 Page 401