Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
The Mediterranean economy 631
The entwining of public and private interests means that the patterns of
sixth- and seventh-century interregional Mediterranean exchange defy easy
synthesis.
86
Butabasic distinction must be drawn between the eastern Mediter-
ranean, where, as we have seen, all the evidence points to a widespread late
antique boom in the rural economy, closely associated with exports to overseas
markets, and the western Mediterranean, where interregional exchange had
been declining in volume and complexity for some time, and was dominated
by African goods. If producers in Spain, Gaul or Italy regularly marketed their
surplus overseas, they rarely did so by transporting their agricultural surplus
in amphorae or shipping fine-ware pottery alongside it, and although African
ceramics continued to be distributed widely around the Mediterraneanthrough
the sixth century and on into the seventh, even here there are signs of a sim-
plification of production before the end of the fifth century.
87
Of the three
main categories of ARS only one, the D ware produced in northern Tunisia,
was still manufactured by c.550, and the number of forms of this ware in circu-
lation diminished considerably over the next century.
88
Late antique African
amphorae cannot yet be classified and dated with similar precision, but the
evidence implies a similar contraction in variety and complexity of production.
The data from African field-surveys around Segermes and Kasserine and in the
Libyan valleys further suggest that rural settlement was already past its peak by
our period, but that this decline began to accelerate from perhaps the mid-sixth
century.
89
In the eastern Mediterranean, by contrast, patterns of production and over-
seas exchange remained far more diverse and polycentric, and the late antique
settlement boom was probably sustained throughout the sixth century. The
preceding period of dramatic expansion and investment may have been over
in some regions, such as the Syrian limestone massif, but this is perhaps better
seen in terms of consolidation rather than stagnation, especially since similar
areas, such as the interior of Palestine, exhibit continuing prosperity. In any
event, there is little sign of any widespread crisis of production or distribution
in the eastern Mediterranean before 600.
90
The scale of production and the
86
Best for the archaeology is Panella (1993), but the characterisation of the seventh century is now too
pessimistic. For a wider overview of fifth- and sixth-century exchange, see Ward-Perkins (2000b).
87
Precisely when this begins, however, is a moot point; its origins may precede the Vandal conquest:
Panella (1993), pp. 641–5.
88
Reynolds (1995), pp. 12–14, 28–34, citing a fall from fifteen forms in 533 to only three a century
later. This may be too precise, but the trend is clear. Cf. Mackensen (1998) for seventh-century ARS
production.
89
Helpful overview (and further references) in Mattingly and Hitchner (1995), esp. pp. 189–96, 209–13.
90
For‘stagnation’ in the limestone massif c.550–610,Tate (1992), pp. 335–42,inmyview overstated;
cf. Orssaud (1992) for ceramic continuity. The lively debate about the general state of Syria and
Palestine in the later sixth century lies outside the scope of this chapter. For overviews see Foss
(1995); Kennedy (2000), and also Louth, chapter 4 above.