Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
The Mediterranean economy 621
Only reports of the muggings of visiting merchants by the rascally local peas-
antry spoil the festive scene. Another staple, which may well have circulated
commercially hereabouts, was grain. Pope Gregory I, for example, was peren-
nially anxious to secure grain-supplies for Rome from Sicily, usually through
imperial functionaries or from the extensive papal estates, but he also resorted
to purchasing it on the open market, in 591 spending fifty pounds of gold
on buying up additional supplies from the island for storage in response to a
poor Roman harvest.
41
Across the Apennines, meanwhile, the inhabitants of
Venetia and Istria at the head of the Adriatic were dealing in wine, fish-sauce,
oil and salt, as well as grain; some of these goods were intended for Ravenna,
but they were also traded on the open market.
42
Tw o centuries later the mer-
chants of Comacchio at the head of the Po would secure from the Lombards an
agreement granting them trading rights along the river in exchange for tolls in
kind, among which salt again figures prominently.
43
Salt is precisely the sort of
commodity that one might expect to circulate over some distance – everybody
needs salt, as Cassiodorus observed – but not too far. Its extraction is widely
possible around the Mediterranean, transporting it over long distances by sea
ran the risk of ruining it, and, unlike wine, specific types of salt are not known
to have carried any premium. Its presence in these texts is one indication that
the exchange they describe is regional in nature.
The early medieval Mediterranean thus sustained a series of regional
economies, some of which appear to have been more developed, or more
dynamic, than others. The variable experiences of Italy’s regions, in particular,
already suggest that generalised explanations of economic change, such as the
impact of warfare or of environmental crisis, are insufficient.
44
The extension
of such studies offers our best hope of developing comparative perspectives and
achieving a deeper understanding of early medieval exchange in all its com-
plexity. But for the Mediterranean economy writ large, we must return to the
exchange which continued to unite those who lived around Rome’s Internal
Sea (and even some out in the Ocean) long after the political fragmentation
of its shores. The term ‘long-distance trade’ conventionally used to describe
this type of traffic is not entirely helpful, because, as we have seen, it is not
distance but access to the sea or to navigable waterways that really matters.
In this sense, the inhabitants of the Spanish coast were ‘closer’ to Carthage or
41
Gregory I, Reg. i.70; Arnaldi (1986). Gregory’s anticipation of crisis seems to have been exceptional:
cf. note 30 above.
42
Cassiodorus, Variae xii.22, 24, the latter showing how the inhabitants of Venetia directly exchanged
cylinders of salt for foodstuffs.
43
Hartmann (1904), pp. 123–4, for the text of the early eighth-century Comacchio ‘capitulary’, trans-
lated and discussed in Balzaretti (1996).
44
Wickham (1994), pp. 752–6,Marazzi (1998b), and for the ceramics Sagu
`
ı(1998).