
MANAGING RESOURCES: NATIONAL INNOVATION SYSTEMS 399
inevitably, resulted in an upward price spiral, which led to increasing profits in the
pharmaceutical industry. Hence, it could, in fact, be argued that this price system
would have, in and of itself, and independently of the safety regulations, encour-
aged the development of mainly local products.
In recent years, however, while still cutting the prices of older drugs, the
Japanese government has only offered premium prices to drugs with a significant
therapeutic advantage, thus driving research programmes towards ‘break-
through’ drugs. Although this measure is said to be part of the MHW’s
cost-containment effort, this case argues that this also contains an industrial
policy aspect in that it forces firms to develop global drugs and punishes those
firms that are unable to do so. Moreover, MHW respondents argued that while
pricing policy is used for health policy reasons, it is also the main, if not sole,
industrial policy instrument (interviews, Tokyo, 1996–97). Consequently, while
this case accepts the argument that, initially, pricing policy could have been used
mainly as healthcare policy, it also claims that eventually, when the effect of
pricing upon industry behaviour was recognized, the MHW combined the use of
pricing policy for healthcare purposes with applying it in order to steer the phar-
maceutical industry, thus also using pricing policy as an industrial policy
instrument.
In a similar vein, this case argues that, in Germany too, pricing policy – which
in Germany means the absence of price controls until the late 1980s – could be
seen as part of an industrial policy with considerable influence on product market
strategy. Rather like Japan, Germany is also well known to be a high-price
country for pharmaceuticals. Table 8.3 shows that Germany is the second
highest-price country in Europe.This case argues that a decided non-interven-
tionist stance in an oligopolistic market is tantamount to interventionism. The
absence of price controls on pharmaceuticals until the end of the 1980s in
Germany, in a market that is known to be oligopolistic, amounts to a policy that
promotes the pharmaceutical industry.
At the end of the 1980s, as part of the cost-containment efforts in the health-
care sector, for the first time in history, the German government decided to
interfere with drug pricing and introduced a fixed-price scheme. The intention
was to stimulate price competition in the pharmaceutical market and to use this
to reduce drug spending. However, by fixing reimbursement levels by therapeutic
category rather than basing the system on individual drugs, the reference price
scheme continues to encourage oligopolistic pricing and discourage radical kinds
of drug innovation within the therapeutic categories.
The incremental bias of the German product market strategy received further
support in 1995, when the German government changed the original fixed-price
scheme. Whereas initially only ‘truly innovative’ drugs were shielded from the
fixed price scheme, from 1995 onwards, on-patent drugs were freed from price
controls. Since ‘on-patent’ drugs do not have to be truly innovative but must
include incremental innovations, the government once again sent a clear signal
to the industry that it continues to support a product market strategy that is
focused on incremental, and thus less costly, innovation.
MG9353 ch08.qxp 10/3/05 8:46 am Page 399