
their power, and so were reluctant either to privatize state enterprises or to encourage large
Taiwanese firms to develop independently of the state’ (Whitley, 1999: 168).
Whitley explains the Taiwanese business system, saying that ‘This ownership
extended to the banks and the bulk of the formal financial sector, and enabled the regime
to provide jobs for its followers as well as influencing the development of the small-firm,
Taiwanese-dominated export sector . . . The KMT domination of the economy was dif-
ferent from that of the military-backed regime in Korea, in that it concentrated more on
state ownership and control of tariffs, import licenses, etc., than on direct control over the
flow of credit to privately owned firms. Although the formal banking system in Taiwan
has been owned and controlled by the state since the war, the regime has not used this
control to direct the flow of capital to favoured private firms pursuing state priorities.
Rather, it has been more concerned to prevent the growth of large Taiwanese enterprises
that had close links to major banks and so has enacted legislation that prohibits banks
from owning shares in borrowers’ companies or forming holding companies that combine
industrial and financial businesses. In general, the banks prefer to lend to the state enter-
prises and the largest privately owned firms that have good mainlander connections, since
the risks are lower and function more as arms of the bureaucracy than as risk-sharing
supporters of industry... As a result, the bulk of the firms in the export-oriented sector
rely more on the informal “curb” market and capital from family and friends for growth
funds than on the formal banking system. This is especially true for the smaller and newer
enterprises that have little or no collateral to support their applications for bank loans. . . .
Consequently, informal, personal networks of trust and support are crucial
to firms’ survival and growth in Taiwan, and the development of large-scale capital-
intensive industries is difficult without strong state support’ (Whitley, 1999: 168–70).
Whitley explains that ‘the regime’s antagonism to large privately owned enterprises
that are independent of the state – buttressed by references to Sun Yat-sen and sharpened
by the ethnic divide – of the state – has prevented long-term collaboration between the
state and large-scale private interests, except in a few cases, such as Formosa Plastics.
Instead, the private, Taiwanese-dominated part of the economy has been largely treated
with official disdain, and relations between state officials and Taiwanese businessmen are
often described as ‘cool’ and ‘distant’ in contrast to those between officials and the leaders
of publicly owned enterprises. As a result, the degree of direct dependence on the state of
most Taiwanese businesses is limited, and the state has found it difficult to gain the cooper-
ation of firms in a particular sector when it did want to achieve a specific objective through
collaboration. This is exacerbated, of course, by the large number of small firms in most
sectors and the traditional distrust of the regime and its agents’ (Whitley, 1999: 170).
Continuing his argument, Whitley states that ‘the traditional Chinese leaders’
concern with limiting the power of private wealth holders, exacerbated by the ethnic
divide between the Taiwanese and the mainlanders, was expressed most strongly in the
conflict over the liberalization of the economy and movement to a more export-oriented
policy at the end of the 1950s. . . . However, more for political reasons than for economic
ones, coupled with strong US pressure, Chiang Kai-shek supported the reform group in
1958, and Taiwan adopted a more liberal, though still state-dominated approach, to
economic management.
‘This boosted the largely Taiwanese-owned export-oriented sector and confirmed the
distinctive division of the political and economic system between mainlanders and
NATIONAL DIVERSITY AND MANAGEMENT 177
MG9353 ch04.qxp 10/3/05 8:43 am Page 177