table of ch. VI (Table 3), were 1876 and 1914. When, as in the first table of that
chapter, he did mention the date 1900, he did so with no comment on its relevance
to his previous argument about monopolization. The period of monopolization as he
had identified it began at about 1900; thus judging by Table 3 of Chapter VI he
could find an effect from before that year (the expansion of empires) and give a
cause from afterward (monopolization)—Lenin, Imperialism, pp. 46, 76–83. For a
different, more detailed, and if possible even less friendly account of Hobson-
Hilferding-Kautsky-Leninist imperialism, see L.H.Gann and Peter Duignan, Burden
of Empire: An Appraisal of Western Colonialism in Africa (Stanford, CA: Hoover
Institution Press, 1967), pp. 39–71. The economic theory of imperialism and its
weaknesses are also explored in Koebner, ‘Concept of Economic Imperialism’;
Mark Blaug, ‘Economic Imperialism Revisited’, Yale Review, ser. 2, 50 (1961), pp.
335–49; and D.K.Fieldhouse, ‘“Imperialism”: An Historiographical Revision’,
Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 25, 2 (1961), pp. 187–209.
47 The argument in favour of a dominant service sector is contained in W.D.
Rubinstein, Capitalism, Culture, and Decline in Britain, 1750–1900 (London:
Routledge, 1993). In the nineteenth century and ever since, British manufacturers
were reputed to possess wealth far in excess of what they actually had. They had a
reputation as a large group helping to guide British policy, when in fact
manufacturers made up only a tiny fraction of society, even in manufacturing
centres—Stana Nenadic, ‘Businessmen, The Urban Middle Class, and the
“Dominance” of Manufacturers in Nineteenth-century Britain’, Economic History
Review, 2nd ser., 44, 1 (1991), pp. 66–85.
48 P.J.Cain and A.G.Hopkins, British Imperialism: Innovation and Expansion, 1688–
1914 (London and New York: Longman, 1993).
49 It has appeared in a new edition: P.J.Cain and A.G.Hopkins, British Imperialism,
1688–2000, 2nd edn (London and New York: Longman, 2002); and it has inspired
new work: see Raymond E.Dumett (ed.), Gentlemanly Capitalism and British
Imperialism: The New Debate on Empire (London and New York: Longman, 1999).
‘Gentlemanly capitalism’, first proposed by Cain and Hopkins in 1986, has proved
to be a fruitful idea for investigating British domestic history quite apart from
imperialism: see e.g. W.D.Rubinstein, ‘“Gentlemanly Capitalism” and British
Industry, 1820–1914: Comment’, Past & Present, 132 (August 1991), pp. 150–70;
M.J Daunton, ‘“Gentlemanly Capitalism” and British Industry, 1820–1914: Reply’,
Past & Present, 132 (August 1991), pp. 170–87; and Daunton, ‘“Gentlemanly
Capitalism” and British Industry, 1820–1914’, Past & Present, 122 (February
1989), pp. 119–58. For the fons et origo, see P.J.Cain and A.G.Hopkins, ‘Gentleman
Capitalism and British Expansion Overseas. I. The Old Colonial System’, Economic
History Review, 2nd ser., 39, 4 (November 1986), pp. 501–25; and ‘Gentlemanly
Capitalism and British Expansion Overseas. II. New Imperialism’, Economic
History Review, 40, 1 (February 1987), pp. 1–26. See also Cain and Hopkins, ‘The
Political Economy of British Expansion Overseas, 1750–1914’, Economic History
Review, 2nd ser., 33, 4 (November 1980), pp. 463–90.
50 A.G.Hopkins, ‘The “New International Economic Order”, in the Nineteenth
Century: Britain’s First Development Plan for Africa’, in Robin Law (ed.), From
Notes 136