6.5 Correlations with Stock Returns: SI versus SV 149
versa. Consequently, call and put options will be overvalued by the Black-Scholes
formula regardless of ITM or OTM. By contrast, a positive correlation between
stock returns and SI causes the fatter tails of the true distribution of stock prices.
Thus, in this case, the Black-Scholes formula undervalues call and put options re-
gardless of moneyness. In Chapter 3, we have discussed stochastic volatility models
in details and found that the Black-Scholes formula overprices OTM call options
and undervalues ITM call options if a negative correlation between stock returns and
SV is present. A positive correlation results in an opposite relation in a stochastic
volatility model. The choice of two alternative correlations in a practical application
is then dependent on which pattern of stock price distribution fits the true distribu-
tion better. This requires more empirical investigations and perhaps changes from
case to case.
Rabinovitch (1989) provided an option pricing formula in a Gaussian model
where interest rates follow a mean-reverting Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process and the
correlation between stock returns and interest rates is allowed. In a single-factor
model of interest rates, the zero-coupon bond pricing formula generally takes the
following form,
B(0,T)=exp[A(T )r
0
+C(T)].
Based on this result, a call option can be valued by the following formula,
3
C = S
0
N(d
1
) −KB(0,T )N(d
2
) (6.33)
with
d
1,2
=
ln(S
0
/K) −lnB(0, T ) ±
1
2
η
2
(T)
η
(T)
(6.34)
and
η
2
(T)=v
2
T +
T
0
[
σ
2
A(t)
2
−2
ρ
v
σ
A(t)]dt. (6.35)
Thus we can take stochastic interest rates and their correlation with stock returns
ρ
into account when the variance v
2
T in the Black-Scholes formula is replaced by
the term
η
2
(T). Note that the function A(T ) in the Vasicek model is deterministic,
the equation (6.35) can be integrated. Formula (6.33) is simple and easy to imple-
ment. If we use A(T) in the Vasicek model, we will obtain the same pricing model
for which a Fourier transform pricing formula is given by the CFs (6.20) and (6.23).
Another alternative model considering such non-zero correlation was developed by
Scott (1997). In his model, stochastic interest rates and stochastic volatilities share
a common state variable which is correlated with stock returns. Obviously, this im-
plies the unappealing feature that correlations of stock returns with interest rates and
with volatilities are same. In addition, it is difficult to identify the two state variables
specified in his model.
3
It is assumed that the volatility v is a bounded deterministic function (see Rabinovich (1989),
or Musiela and Rutkowski (2005)). Hence, stochastic volatilities can not be incorporated into this
pricing formula.