x are cointegrated, and we call
the cointegration parameter. [Alternatively, we could
look at x
t
y
t
for
0: if y
t
x
t
is I(0), then x
t
(1/
)y
t
is I(0). Therefore, the
linear combination of y
t
and x
t
is not unique, but if we fix the coefficient on y
t
at unity,
then
is unique. See Problem 18.3. For concreteness, we consider linear combinations
of the form y
t
x
t
.]
For the sake of illustration, take
1, suppose that y
0
x
0
0, and write y
t
y
t1
r
t
, x
t
x
t1
v
t
, where {r
t
} and {v
t
} are two I(0) processes with zero means.
Then, y
t
and x
t
have a tendency to wander around and not return to the initial value of
zero with any regularity. By contrast, if y
t
x
t
is I(0), it has zero mean and does return
to zero with some regularity.
As a specific example, let r6
t
be the annualized interest rate for six-month, T-bills
(at the end of quarter t) and let r3
t
be the annualized interest rate for three-month,
T-bills. (These are typically called bond equivalent yields, and they are reported in the
financial pages.) In Example 18.2, using the data in INTQRT.RAW, we found little evi-
dence against the hypothesis that r3
t
has a unit root; the same is true of r6
t
. Define the
spread between six- and three-month, T-bill rates as spr
t
r6
t
r3
t
. Then, using equa-
tion (18.21), the Dickey-Fuller t statistic for spr
t
is 7.71 (with
ˆ
.67 or
ˆ
.33).
Therefore, we strongly reject a unit root for spr
t
in favor of I(0). The upshot of this is
that while r6
t
and r3
t
each appear to be unit root processes, the difference between them
is an I(0) process. In other words, r6 and r3 are cointegrated.
Cointegration in this example, as in many examples, has an economic interpretation.
If r6 and r3 were not cointegrated, the difference between interest rates could become
very large, with no tendency for them to come back together. Based on a simple arbi-
trage argument, this seems unlikely. Suppose that the spread spr
t
continues to grow for
several time periods, making six-month T-bills a much more desirable investment.
Then, investors would shift away from three-month and toward six-month T-bills, dri-
ving up the price of six-month T-bills, while lowering the price of three-month T-bills.
Since interest rates are inversely related to price, this would lower r6 and increase r3,
until the spread is reduced. Therefore, large deviations between r6 and r3 are not
expected to continue: the spread has a tendency to return to its mean value. (The spread
actually has a slightly positive mean because long-term investors are more rewarded rel-
ative to short-term investors.)
There is another way to characterize the fact that spr
t
will not deviate for long peri-
ods from its average value: r6 and r3 have a long-run relationship. To describe what we
mean by this, let
E(spr
t
) denote the expected value of the spread. Then, we can
write
r6
t
r3
t
e
t
,
where {e
t
} is a zero mean, I(0) process. The equilibrium or long-run relationship occurs
when e
t
0, or r6* r3*
. At any time period, there can be deviations from equi-
librium, but they will be temporary: there are economic forces that drive r6 and r3 back
toward the equilibrium relationship.
In the interest rate example, we used economic reasoning to tell us the value of
if
y
t
and x
t
are cointegrated. If we have a hypothesized value of
, then testing whether
two series are cointegrated is easy: we simply define a new variable, s
t
y
t
x
t
, and
apply either the usual DF or augmented DF test to {s
t
}. If we reject a unit root in {s
t
}
Chapter 18 Advanced Time Series Topics
587
d 7/14/99 8:36 PM Page 587