
984 politics and scientific enquiry
roommates who must live with a single thermostat setting). In any unitary model,
either A or B must be the ruler or dictator. If, however, both are participants in the
decision process, neither A nor B can uniquely determine which alternative is to be
chosen. The alternatives, as such, are not within the choice set of either participant.
The participants can, of course, order the alternatives and agreement may be reached
on some process or rule for making a selection.
It seems evident that the disjuncture between a person’s ordering of the alternatives
and that same person’s expressed “choices” (votes) in processes in which other per-
sons are known to participate becomes a possible source for differences in behavior.
Further, it seems clear that characteristics or attributes of a person’s ordering of
alternatives need not necessarily correspond to the characteristics or attributes of that
same person’s “choice” behavior in the process of selection. In different words, there is
no necessary mapping between the individual’s evaluative orderings of the collective
alternatives and the ranking of the choices that would be made as participation in the
institutions of collective selection, including voting, takes place. There is a logically
derived attenuation between these two orderings that stems from the absence of full
responsibility for choice.
2
Methodological clarity, if nothing else, would seem to dictate that these categor-
ically differing models of state or collective action be separately analyzed in parallel
tracks, rather than incoherently intermingled. In this respect, only the Italian fiscal
theorists who developed their primary contributions over the course of a century,
roughly, 1850–1950, are deserving of special commendation. These scholars, among
whose names would be placed Ferrara, Pantaleoni, Mazzola, de Viti de Marco, Ein-
audi, Puviani, Fasiani, Cosciani, Barone, along with others, did not neglect attention
to the model of the collective unit subject to analysis. De Viti de Marco and Fasiani, in
particular, wrote treatises in which the two models, that of the unitary or monopoly
state and that of the cooperative or democratic state, were presented side by side.
3
Interestingly enough, Duncan Black and I, who were early contributors to the “new”
approach to the analysis of politics in mid-century and later, were both exposed, early
in our own research programs, to this Italian tradition in fiscal theory.
5 Theory of “Democratic”Politics
.............................................................................
As noted, residues of the organic state model of collective action remain in modern
analyses, and especially in the sense that much enquiry seems to be informed by a
longing for patterns of collective action that would, in fact, be comparable to those
² For early discussion, see Buchanan 1954.Notethatthedisjunctureheredoesnotdepend,inanyway,
on the logical grounds for expressive voting that emerge only in large-number electoral settings. For
discussion of expressive voting, see Brennan and Buchanan 1984 and Brennan and Lomasky 1993.
³ For a general summary overview of the whole Italian tradition in public finance, see Buchanan 1960.
The only major work in English translation is de Viti de Marco 1936. In Italian, see Fasiani 1951.