in some point within W(SQ), and if it were at SQ1, they would move it inside W(SQ1). They
would be able to include more items in the government program the further away the status quo
is, and the closer they are to each other as we have seen in the first part of this book. In particular
Figure 1.7 and Proposition 1.4 demonstrate that what matters is not the number of veto players
but the size of their unanimity core.
Now, suppose that some exogenous shock replaces an existing outcome. The underlying
assumption in the “events approach” literature is that the size of the shock matters, and some of
them are too big for certain governments to handle. I will show that this is an inaccurate way of
thinking about the problem. In my model there are two possibilities: this movement can be
“manageable” or “non-manageable.” By manageable movement I mean a replacement of SQ that
either is very close the government program (that is, the shock in effect simulates government
policy, so no further action is necessary), or, the new SQ moves away from its previous position,
so that the government program is still included in W(SQ). In Figure 9.1 moving the status quo
from SQ1 to SQ1’ or vice versa is a manageable situation, because the coalition can respond by
leaving SQ1’ or moving back to SQ1’ as the case may be. What is of interest in this example is
that the size of the shock is not necessarily related to whether the situation is manageable. It is
possible that large shocks are easily manageable.
127
By contrast, the situation is non-manageable if the change in status quo has made an
agreement among veto players impossible. For example, if SQ is moved to SQ’ in Figure 9.1 an
agreement to go back to whatever solution was included in the government program (it had to be
within W(SQ)) is impossible. Again, non-manageable situations are not necessarily the result of
large shocks.
127
For example, if the new position of SQ is covered (see definition in Chapter 1) by the old one the situation is
manageable.