I also argue that the veto players variable is not dependent on institutions or party
systems alone, but derived from of both of them. For example, veto players include not only
partners in government, but also second chambers of the legislature, or presidents of the republic
(if they have veto power). In addition, a party may be significant in parliament and count in the
party system of a country, but its approval of a legislative measure may not be required in which
case it will not be a veto player. Finally, one or more veto players whether a government partner,
a second chamber, or a president of the republic may be absorbed and not count as veto players
as demonstrated in Chapter 1.
The question whether it is minsters that control the agenda or the whole government is a
minor one, however since my approach shares Laver and Shepsle the importance attributed to
agenda setting, I need to clarify that some empirical evidence conflicting with their expectations
does not affect my analysis.
Equally trivial may seem the difference on whether the relationship between governments
and parliaments is determined on the basis of government duration or agenda setting rules. Yet,
government duration varies only in parliamentary systems, ans consequently cannot be used as a
proxy of executive domiance in presidential systems, or across systems; agenda setting rules can
be used across systems. In addition, I argue that there is no logical relationship between
executive dominance and government duration, so a different variable is necessary for the study
of the relationship between legislative and executive. I demonstrate that this relationship can be
capured by the rules regulating legislative agenda setting.
The chapter is organized in three sections. Section I studies the positional conditions of
agenda setting. I focus on different kinds of parliamentary governments (minimum winning
coalitions, oversized governments and minority governments) and study their ability to impose