3
I 8 THE WARLORD ERA, 1916-28
Warlord demand for money was insatiable, and the militarists wrung
an astonishing array of taxes from the populace. They also printed wor-
thless currency on a large scale and forced people to accept it, thus making
commercial transactions a form of expropriation. In late 1924 it was
estimated that in the single province of Kwangsi the military had issued
five billion Chinese dollars in virtually unbacked notes. This enormous
drain of wealth to military and other unproductive purposes inhibited
orderly economic activity and planning, particularly for large-scale pro-
jects,
and thus surely retarded China's economic development.'
6
Warlordism nurtured famine. In some provinces, warlords forced the
cultivation of opium as a cash crop, thus reducing the acreage devoted
to food crops. Diminishing government appropriations to maintain ir-
rigation and flood control facilities helped to bring about several disas-
trous floods. Troops seized draught animals from peasants, not only
imposing a direct economic loss but reducing the productivity of peasant
farming. Devastating famines in North China during the mid and late
1920s were so clearly the product of warlord misgovernment that the
China International Famine Relief Commission, which was chartered to
aid victims of famine due to natural causes, had to change its definition
of famine so that it could render aid to people who were starving from
conditions caused by misgovernment and exploitation. In fact, the
American Red Cross refused to participate in China famine relief at that
time because the famine was created by political, not natural, phenomena."
In many areas, the actions of organized armies were less serious than
the hordes of uncontrolled and undisciplined soldiers who roamed the
countryside preying on the peasantry. A study by the South Manchurian
Railway in 1930 - two years after the warlord period was supposed to
have ended - estimated that in the province of Shantung 310,000 unor-
ganized troops and bandits, in addition to 192,000 regular troops, were
living off the countryside.'
8
Banditry flourished in all parts of the country,
and robbery and violence were commonplace. Victorious troops looted
whenever they could. Wars often destroyed civilian lives and property,
activity such as the development of industry, agriculture, transport and education. A good
example of this view is Thomas G. Rawski, China's
republican
economy:
an
introduction.
Vir-
tually
every student of warlordism acknowledges the constructive activities of some war-
lords.
But, on balance, the consequences of warlordism can not reasonably be considered
positive,
and the notion that oppression and harshness were not widespread flies in the face
of
a large number of
testimonials
based on first-hand experience or observation.
36
For an attempt to calculate the funds diverted to military
uses,
away from possible use in
economic
modernization, see Jerome Ch'en, The military-gentry
coalition,
189-90.
37
Nathan, Andrew
James,
A
history
of
the
China
International
¥amine Relief
Commission,
40-56.
38
Mantetsu Chosabu, 'Shina no doran to Santo noson' (Shantung villages and the upheaval
in
China) (Dairen,
1930),
20, 27, cited in Ramon H.
Myers,
The
Chinese
peasant
economy:
agricultural development
in Hopti
and
Shantung,
1890-1949, 278.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008