
9.4 Nonzero-Sum Games 275
reference to the cost function of the other player. Because of the assumed de-
terministic character, the strategy of the opponent may be fixed. Then we say
a pair of actions u
∗
1
and u
∗
2
is a Nash equilibrium if
J
∗
1
= J
1
(u
∗
1
,u
∗
2
) = min
u
1
∈U
1
J
1
(u
1
,u
∗
2
) (9.42)
and
J
∗
2
= J
2
(u
∗
1
,u
∗
2
) = min
u
2
∈U
2
J
2
(u
∗
1
,u
2
) (9.43)
Obviously, a Nash equilibrium can be detected in a pair of matrices J
1
and
J
2
by finding a matrix position (u
1
,u
2
) such that the corresponding element
J
1
(u
1
,u
2
) is the lowest among all elements in the column u
2
of J
1
and the
element J
2
(u
1
,u
2
) is the lowest among all elements in row u
1
of J
2
. Let us
illustrate this procedure by a simple example. We consider the matrices
J
1
=
1 −1 0 2
30 14
21−2 3
J
2
=
−1 −1 12
2 0 21
421 2
(9.44)
It is simple to check that the Nash equilibria exist for the positions (1, 1),
(1, 2), and (3, 3). It is a typical feature that a nonzero game has multiple
Nash equilibria. From a first glance, the Nash equilibrium at (1, 2) seems to
be the best choice because it yields negative costs for both players. However,
the general decision as to which Nash equilibrium is the optimal choice is by
no means a trivial procedure.
The simplest case occurs if both players do not have the same rights.
Then, one player, say player 1, is the master player while the second one is
the slave. Under this consideration a lexicographic order of the Nash equilibria
defines the optimal solution. That means, firstly we search for the pair (J
∗
1
,J
∗
2
)
which has the lowest value of J
∗
1
. If two or more pairs satisfy this condition,
we consider that pair of these candidates which has also the lowest value
of J
∗
2
. In our example such a concept would lead to the decision that the
nash equilibrium at (3, 3) is the optimal choice. That should be the typical
situation for possible intrinsic control mechanisms of complex systems. The
first decision comes from the main controller, and only if it cannot give a
unique answer, does the second controller decide the common strategy.
The situation becomes much more complicated if both players have equal
rights. Then the definition of the best solution implies a suitable ordering
of the Nash equilibria. It is often only a partial ordering procedure because
some pairs (J
∗
1
,J
∗
2
) are incomparable
5
. In the last case, the player must com-
municate or collaborate in order to avoid higher costs. If the players do not
find an agreement, the possibility of higher costs is often unavoidable. For
example, this is the case if both players favor actions which are related to
5
For example the pairs (0, 1) and (1, 0) cannot be ordered under the assumption
of players with equal rights.