CHAPTER 18
International Trade
341
• Efficient production of various goods requires
different technologies or combinations of resources.
• Products are differentiated as to quality and other
nonprice attributes. A few or many people may prefer
certain imported goods to similar goods made
domestically.
To recognize the character and interaction of these three
facts, think of Japan, for example, which has a large,
well-educated labor force and abundant, and therefore
inexpensive, skilled labor. As a result, Japan can produce
efficiently (at low cost) a variety of labor-intensive goods
such as digital cameras, video game players, and DVD
players whose design and production require much skilled
labor.
In contrast, Australia has vast amounts of land and can
inexpensively produce such land-intensive goods as
wheat, wool, and meat. Brazil has the soil, tropical climate,
rainfall, and ready supply of unskilled labor that are needed
for the efficient, low-cost production of coffee.
Industrially advanced economies with relatively large
amounts of capital can inexpensively produce goods whose
production requires much capital, including such capital-
intensive goods as automobiles, agricultural equipment,
machinery, and chemicals.
All nations, regardless of their labor, land, or capital
intensity, can find special niches for individual products
that are in demand worldwide because of their special
qualities. Examples: fashions from Italy, luxury automo-
biles from Germany, software from the United States, and
watches from Switzerland.
The distribution of resources, technology, and prod-
uct distinctiveness among nations, however, is not forever
fixed. When that distribution changes, the relative effi-
ciency and success with which nations produce and sell
goods also changes. For example, in the past few decades
South Korea has upgraded the quality of its labor force
and has greatly expanded its stock of capital. Although
South Korea was primarily an exporter of agricultural
products and raw materials a half-century ago, it now ex-
ports large quantities of manufactured goods. Similarly,
the new technologies that gave us synthetic fibers and syn-
thetic rubber drastically altered the resource mix needed
to produce these goods and changed the relative efficiency
of nations in manufacturing them.
As national economies evolve, the size and quality of
their labor forces may change, the volume and composi-
tion of their capital stocks may shift, new technologies may
develop, and even the quality of land and the quantity of
natural resources may be altered. As such changes occur,
the relative efficiency with which a nation can produce spe-
cific goods will also change.
Comparative Advantage:
Graphical Analysis
Implicit in what we have been saying is the principle of
comparative advantage, described through production
possibilities tables in Chapter 5. Let’s look again at that
idea, now using graphical analysis.
Two Isolated Nations
Suppose the world economy is composed of just two
nations: the United States and Brazil. Also for simplicity,
suppose that the labor forces in the United States and
Brazil are of equal size. Each nation can produce both
wheat and coffee, but at different levels of economic effi-
ciency. Suppose the U.S. and Brazilian domestic produc-
tion possibilities curves for coffee and wheat are as shown
in Figure 18.1a and 18.1b . Note especially three realities
relating to these production possibilities curves:
• Constant costs The “curves” are drawn as straight lines,
in contrast to the bowed-outward production possibili-
ties frontiers we examined in Chapter 1. This means
that we have replaced the law of increasing opportunity
costs with the assumption of constant costs. This substi-
tution simplifies our discussion but does not impair the
validity of our analysis and conclusions. Later we will
consider the effects of increasing opportunity costs.
• Different costs The production possibilities curves of
the United States and Brazil reflect different resource
mixes and differing levels of technological progress.
Specifically, the differing slopes of the two curves tell
us that the opportunity costs of producing wheat and
coffee differ between the two nations.
• U.S. absolute advantage in both In view of our
assumption that the U.S. and Brazilian labor forces
are of equal size, the two production possibilities
curves show that the United States has an absolute
advantage in producing both products. If the
United States and Brazil use their entire (equal-size)
labor forces to produce either coffee or wheat, the
United States can produce more of either than
Brazil. The United States, using the same number
of workers as Brazil, has greater production possibil-
ities. So output per worker—labor productivity—in
the United States exceeds that in Brazil in producing
both products.
United States In Figure 18.1a , with full employment,
the United States will operate on its production possibilities
curve. On that curve, it can increase its output of wheat from
0 tons to 30 tons by forgoing 30 tons of coffee output. This
mcc73082_ch18_338-359.indd 341mcc73082_ch18_338-359.indd 341 9/15/06 4:04:00 PM9/15/06 4:04:00 PM
CONFIRMING PAGES