Guildsmen and handicraft producers
combination of implements and raw materials is at issue, the meaning is often
explained in eighteenth-century official documents. We can thus assume that
the second use of the term was the less familiar one.
In seventeenth-century Ottoman records, and even in texts from the early
1700s, references to gediks are quite rare. When, as we have seen, Istanbul
bakers selling underweight bread were to be punished by the confiscation of
their implements and shop inventories, and the sale of these items to other
bakers on behalf of the imperial treasury, there was no reference to the loss
of their gediks(1720). It is hard to imagine that in this context, the term could
have been avoided if it had been applicable at that time. Therefore in this
important Istanbul craft, gediks probably were not of major importance in
the early eighteenth century. In the case of seventeenth-century Bursa, guild
organisation seems to have been even looser; apparently the main criterion
for membership was the fact that a master paid his taxes along with his fellow
guildsmen. In the course of their active lives, certain craftsmen might even
belong to more than one guild.
58
This sort of flexibility obviously became
impossible once the exercise of a given craft was normally tied to the holding
of a gedik.
Even in the sixteenth century, established craftsmen had attempted to make
entry into their crafts difficult to newcomers.
59
But these attempts probably
became even more frequent in the second half of the eighteenth century, after
the prosperity that many craft sectors had enjoyed between the 1720s and
the 1760s ended abruptly with the Russo-Ottoman war of 1768–74.
60
Thus
it has been suggested that growing demands for rent on the part of pious
foundations, which, as we have seen, so often owned the shops occupied by
Istanbul craftsmen, constituted a major reason for gedik formation.
61
With the
support of urban kadis, craftsmen thus supposedly developed a new form of
property, alienable only within a small circle of people. By limiting demand
for shops and workshops, this arrangement made rent hikes more difficult,
albeit at the price of limiting labour mobility. But then all processes enhancing
labour mobility always had seemed rather threatening to Ottoman (and other)
guildsmen. Moreover, the frequent holding of spaces in collective workshops,
discussed above, along with the intensified mutual control which this entailed,
may also have furthered entry restrictions. Whenever the exercise of a given
58 Gerber, Bursa,pp.35–7. 59 Inalcık, ‘Capital Formation’, pp. 116–17.
60 Mehmet Genc¸, ‘L’Economie ottomane et la guerre au XVIIIe si
`
ecle’, Turcica 27 (1995),
177–96.
61 Engin Akarlı, ‘Gedik: Implements, Mastership, Shop Usufruct, and Monopoly among
Istanbul Artisans, 1750–1850’, Wissenschaftskolleg-Jahrbuch (1984–5), 223–32.
353
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008