suraiya n. faroqhi
on yearly tax-farm revenues useless, as the tax-farmer now paid a fixed sum
for the remainder of his life. However, the entry fine, levied whenever a new
tax-farmer took over, should still allow us to determine whether textile pro-
duction was expanding or declining.
8
In the case of industries with heavy state
demand, such as the manufacture of sailcloth or fabric for military uniforms,
orders for textiles may provide a rough notion of productive capacities. Lists of
administratively fixed prices, especially for Istanbul, provide some indication
of the fabrics originating from provincial towns available in the markets of the
capital, and thus also about internal trade in textiles.
9
As for raw cotton, silk or mohair exports, figures are available from English,
French and Dutch sources. If we possessed some idea of overall production of
these essential raw materials, which in most cases we do not, we would know
where, and to what extent, scarcities due to excessive exportation crippled
Ottoman artisan production. However, European documents also contain a
fair amount of information on prices, which may be useful when we wish
to judge the production costs of Ottoman craftsmen.
10
Admittedly, caution is
in order, as Ottoman textile producers might live closer to the source of raw
material than exporters, and therefore pay lower transportation costs. Or else
they might enjoy privileged access to materials such as raw wool, as was true
of the Jewish artisans of Salonika.
11
Certain qualities of fibre even might be
reserved for local producers exclusively, as in the later eighteenth and early
nineteenth centuries, was the rule in the Ankara mohair industry.
12
Ye t g ive n
the relative scarcity of such information in Ottoman documents, these data
gleaned from European sources, whatever their limitations, still constitute
worthwhile indicators of textile production in the lands bordering the eastern
Mediterranean.
In addition, qualitative evidence should not be neglected. Disputes between
textile-producing artisans and tax-farmers, between the former and the admin-
istrators of pious foundations renting out workspace, and, last but not least,
among fellow guildsmen themselves, provide useful information on the condi-
tions under which production took place. Artisans’ attempts to hold their own
8 Mehmet Genc¸, ‘Osmanlı maliyesinde malik
ˆ
ane sistemi’, in T
¨
urkiye iktisat tarihi semineri,
ed. Osman Okyar and
¨
Unal Nabanto
˘
glu (Ankara, 1975), pp. 231–96.
9 M
¨
ubahat K
¨
ut
¨
uko
˘
glu, Osmanlılarda narh m
¨
uessesesi ve 1640 tarihli narh defteri (Istanbul,
1983).
10 Elena Frangakis-Syrett, The Commerce of Smyrna in the Eighteenth Century (1700–1820)
(Athens, 1992).
11 Suraiya Faroqhi, ‘Textile Production in Rumeli and the Arab Provinces: Geographical
Distribution and Internal Trade’, Osmanlı Aras¸tırmaları 1 (1980), 61–83 at p. 68.
12 Suraiya Faroqhi, ‘Mohair Manufacture and Mohair Workshops in Seventeenth Century
Ankara’,
˙
Istanbul
¨
Universitesi
˙
Iktisat Fak
¨
ultesi Mecmuası 41, 1–4 (1982–3), 211–36.
358
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008