
hours, taking standard retirement at the age of 60, signing a new, obligation-free contract
with the company at the age of 60, work sharing after 60, or permanent secondment to
an affiliated company. A counselling service is available to help employees decide which
path to follow. Hence, while a plethora of articles in the Japanese and US popular business
press predict the demise of lifetime employment, these new conditions of employment
clearly represent modification of lifetime employment, not a contradiction of it (Kono and
Clegg, 2001: 12–13). Indeed, while many companies are implementing changes, it would
be inaccurate on this basis to proclaim the end of the current system, since the system has
always been evolving rather than remaining stable (Ornatowski, 1998).
There are some very good reasons to continue protecting employment security in
Japanese labour markets. First, Japanese employment security is firmly grounded in legal
precedents set by the Japanese court, which has made it almost impossible for employers
to dismiss or lay off their regular-status employees without the employees’ or their
unions’ consent. Second, both long-term employment and employment security have
been explicit policies of the Japanese government. Third, among the bargaining areas of
Japanese enterprise unions, wage increases have always been considered in tandem with
the protection of employment security for the firm’s permanent workforce. Wage issues
have always been relegated to second place relative to employment security and, when
employment security has been threatened, Japanese enterprise unions engaged in tough
and often violent negotiations (Morishima, 1995). Moreover, lifetime employment is, in
fact, an important part of Japanese management practices as a whole because it reduces
the incredible commitment problems associated with firm-based private-sector training.
Lifetime employment provides incentives for workers to stay with the company that trains
them which, in turn, makes it safe for the firm to invest heavily in skills without fear of
workers leaving, and taking these skills to other firms (Thelen and Kume, 1999). While,
as indicated, lifetime employment, combined with internal promotion ladders and con-
tinuous in-company training, hampers radical innovation, it is an essential ingredient of
the cooperative relationship between producers and suppliers working on a high-quality
and just-in-time basis.
Similar to the situation in Sweden and Japan, in general, German manufacturing
firms do not have a great degree of flexibility in adjusting the size of their workforces
through layoffs, subcontracting, or transfers or loans to other firms. In international com-
parisons, Germany is generally believed to have the most extensive restrictions on layoffs
and dismissals (Büchtemann, 1993: 274). Layoffs are costly, complex, restricted by law as
to required notice, and essentially must meet a ‘just cause’ test. Moreover, high employ-
ment stability is imposed on firms through collective agreements, codetermination and
legislation. While there are no formal laws stipulating long-term employment, German
labour has used its power on supervisory boards, as well as its formal consultative rights
under codetermination law over training, work organization and hiring, to demand
unlimited employment (Casper, 2000). The employment relationship, which has evolved
under the influence of legislation on the rights and obligations of workers within the
enterprise during the postwar period, has given workers high de facto employment
security (Lane, 1989).
For a major employee dislocation like a plant closure, the German regulations con-
tained in the Dismissal Protection Act 1951 (amended in 1969) are among the most
comprehensive among advanced nations. Approximately 80 per cent of those workers
226 COMPARATIVE INTERNATIONAL MANAGEMENT
MG9353 ch05.qxp 10/3/05 8:44 am Page 226