Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
P1: GDZ
0521812909c13 CB929-Bulmer 052181290 9 October 6, 2005 10:44
540 Stephen Haber
Argentina – boasted sizable manufacturing sectors, which produced a broad
range of consumer nondurables (particularly beer, cigarettes, soap, matches,
hats, paper, footwear, and cotton cloth). In some cases, domestic firms
had also moved into the production of intermediate inputs (basic chemi-
cals, glass bottles) and construction goods (particularly cement, explosives,
bricks, steel rails, and iron and steel structural shapes).
The impetus for industrial development came from the expansion of
foreign trade. Driving the growth of foreign trade were two factors. The
first was that most Latin American countries were on the silver standard,
and silver fell in value relative to gold in the last two decades of the nine-
teenth century. Most Latin American countries, therefore, saw their cur-
rencies depreciate in real terms relative to the gold-backed currencies of
the economies of the North Atlantic. As international trade theory would
predict, real exchange rate depreciation resulted in the expansion of the
tradables sectors at the expense of nontradables. Second, the late nine-
teenth century also saw a dramatic decline in the international costs of
transport, as steel-hulled steamships came to replace wood and sail.
Real exchange rate depreciation and falling costs of maritime transport
kick-started Latin American economic growth. Latin American countries
could now produce and ship goods at a price low enough to be competitive
in the United States and Western Europe. These exports included min-
erals (particularly copper and lead), industrial fibers (cotton, wool, jute,
and sisal), staple agricultural goods (primarily beef and wheat), and non-
staple agricultural commodities (the most important of which were coffee,
bananas, and sugar). The result was a wave of foreign direct investment in
precisely those sectors. In order for these investments to bear fruit, how-
ever, there had to be a means to move commodities from their point of
production to the ports or, in the case of Mexico, to the U.S. border. Trade
therefore gave rise to the construction of railroad networks (also financed
by foreign investment) that crisscrossed Latin America, linking major cities
and integrating markets.
3
3
Most of the best work done to date on railroads focuses on the cases of Brazil and Mexico. See, for
example, the chapter in this volume by William Summerhill. Also see his “Transport Improvements
and Economic Growth in Brazil and Mexico,” in Stephen Haber, ed., How Latin America Fell Behind:
Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800–1914 (Stanford,CA, 1997), 93–117, and Order
Against Progress: Government, Foreign Investment, and Railroads in Brazil, 1854–1913 (Stanford, CA,
2003). On Mexico, see Sandra Kuntz Ficker, Empresa extranjera y mercado interno: el Ferrocarril Central
Mexicano, 1880–1907 (Mexico City, 1995); Sandra Kuntz Ficker and Paolo Riguzzi, eds., Ferrocarriles y
vida econ
´
omica en M
´
exico, 1850–1950:Del surgimiento tard
´
ıo al decaimiento precoz (Mexico City, 1996);
and John H. Coatsworth, Growth Against Development: The Economic Impact of Railroads in Porfirian
Mexico (Dekalb, IL, 1981).