
70 3 Stochastic Volatility Models
Table (3.5) display the similar properties as shown in Table (3.2). Firstly, we find
again that options with different moneyness react to the correlation
ρ
oppositely. For
ITM options, their values decrease with the values of correlation. And OTM options
display a wholly opposite relation with the correlation
ρ
to ITM options. Secondly,
the finding in Subsection 3.3.3 that the bias between the long term mean
θ
and the
spot volatility is important for the prices of options is confirmed. In Panel K we have
θ
= 0.208 and spot volatility as
√
0.04 = 0.2, then option prices in this panel are
overall near these two BS benchmarks regardless of moneyness and correlation. In
contrast to Panel K, the panels L and M are calculated with a spot volatility of 0.1
and 0.3 respectively. Consequently, the option prices in these panels deviate from
BS
1
and BS
2
significantly. Finally, as reported in Subsection 3.3.3, options with
different moneyness present different sensitivity to the correlation
ρ
. While OTM
options are generally sensitive to correlation, ITM options do not change remarkably
with
ρ
. Not surprisingly, we can calibrate the implied volatilities from the data with
the negative correlation in Table (3.5) to capture the empirical volatility smile and
sneer pattern.
Table (3.6) shows the impact of
κ
on option prices. Panel N gives all BS
1
values
since every
κ
corresponds to a
θ
, and each BS
1
is then the benchmark for the option
prices in the corresponding position in the panels O, P and Q. In the case of
κ
= 0.1,
θ
has an extraordinary high value of 0.625 and leads to unsuitable benchmarks. One
obvious finding is that the option price is a decreasing function of
κ
regardless of the
moneyness of options. This phenomenon can be explained as follows: For a fixed
σ
,
the values of the explicit
θ
=
σ
2
/(4
κ
) go up with the falling values of
κ
, and im-
ply a larger mean level of the weighted sum
κ
V(t)+
λ
v(t). Hence, option prices
increase correspondingly. A comparison of panels O, P and Q shows that the true
values of options result from a trade-off between long-term mean and spot volatil-
ity. By its very nature, the BS model can not reflect the dynamic effect of varying
volatilities on the option prices. Based on the above observations most of which are
identical to the models of square root process and Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, we
conclude that modeling stochastic volatility with a double square root process also
constitutes a promising way in improving the pricing and hedging performance in
practice.
3.5 Other Stochastic Volatility Models
In above sections, we have addressed three stochastic volatility models that admit
analytical CFs under different measures, and therefore also analytical pricing for-
mulas in form of the Fourier inversion. There are some extensions of these three
stochastic volatility models. For example, N
¨
ogel and Mikhailov (2003) considered
the Heston model with time-dependent parameters by iteratively solving the valua-
tion PDEs at discrete time points. Popovici (2003) extended the Sch
¨
obel-Zhu model
by introducing a time-deterministic function for mean level
θ
, and the new process
for stochastic volatility reads