(The R-squared is identically zero since there are no explanatory variables. But
ˆ
, which
estimates the standard deviation of the error, is comparable to that in part (ii), and we see that it
is much smaller here.) The t statistic for the intercept is about –1.60, which is not significant at
the 10% level against a two-sided alternative. Therefore, it is legitimate to treat gfr
t
as having no
drift, if it is indeed a random walk. (That is, if gfr
t
=
α
0
+ gfr
t-1
+ e
t
, where {e
t
} is zero-mean,
serially uncorrelated process, then we cannot reject H
0
:
α
0
= 0.)
(v) The prediction of gfr
n+1
is simply gfr
n
, so the predication error is simply Δgfr
n+1
= gfr
n+1
–
gfr
n
. Obtaining the MAE for the five prediction errors for 1980 through 1984 gives MAE
.840,
which is much lower than the 43.02 obtained with the cubic trend model. The random walk is
clearly preferred for forecasting.
(vi) The estimated AR(2) model for gfr
t
is
= 3.22 + 1.272 gfr
ˆ
t
gfr
t-1
– .311 gfr
t-2
(2.92) (0.120) (.121)
n = 65, R
2
= .949,
ˆ
= 4.25.
The second lag is significant. (Recall that its t statistic is valid even though gfr
t
apparently
contains a unit root: the coefficients on the two lags sum to .961.) The standard error of the
regression is slightly below that of the random walk model.
(vii) The out-of-sample forecasting performance of the AR(2) model is worse than the
random walk without drift: the MAE for 1980 through 1984 is about .991 for the AR(2) model.
[Instructor’s Note: You might have the students compare an AR(1) model for ∆gfr
t
− that is,
impose the unit root − to the random walk without drift model. The MAE is about .879, so it is
better to impose the unit root. But this still does less well than the simple random walk without
drift.]
18.18 (i) Using the data up through 1989 gives
ˆ
t
= 3,186.04 + 116.24 t + .630 y
t-1
(1,163.09) (46.31) (.148)
n = 30, R
2
= .994,
ˆ
= 223.95.
(Notice how high the R-squared is. However, it is meaningless as a goodness-of-fit measure
because {y
t
} has a trend and possibly a unit root.)
(ii) The forecast for 1990 (t = 32) is 3,186.04 + 116.24(32) + .630(17,804.09)
18,122.30,
because y is $17,804.09 in 1989. The actual value for real per capita disposable income was
$17,944.64, and so the forecast error is –$177.66.
≈
(iii) The MAE for the 1990s, using the model estimated in part (i), is about 371.76.
187