Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
yoram gorlizki and oleg khlevniuk
already brutal regime into a terrorist dictatorship, the excesses of which were
gratuitous and unnecessary by any standards.
3
On matters of policy Stalin was
also extremely stubborn. Ideological concessions and policy retreats were, on
the whole, only wrung out of him under considerable duress, normally when
the country was teetering on the edge of crisis. Augmented by a personality
cult, which tended to present it as a mark of the leader’s ‘infallibility’, this
obduracy would, as towards the end of his life, when Stalin steadfastly blocked
much-needed reforms in key sectors, cost his country dear.
For all its brutality and bloody-mindedness, this position of ‘firmness’ did,
from Stalin’s perspective, serve a particular purpose: to secure his own posi-
tion as the leader of a separate, powerful and respected socialist state. Many of
Stalin’s actions were guided by quite rational calculations towards the attain-
ment of this goal.
4
While this pragmatism has most often been observed in
Stalin’s behaviour on the international stage, it was also evident in domestic
affairs. Perhaps nowhere was this more apparent than in Stalin’s relations with
his immediate colleagues. Despite a reputation for arbitrary brutality, Stalin
systematically promoted younger functionaries and treated with great care
those high-level leaders whose qualities, either as workers or as symbols of the
revolution, he valued; after the Great Purges in particular, this was a group
towards which the leader exhibited a surprising degree of self-restraint and
moderation.
5
The attention Stalin paid his colleagues was fully merited, for these deputies
played an indispensable role in running the Soviet state. Well known in their
own right, most members of the Politburo managed important portfolios and
headed powerful personal networks. In two periods – during the war and in
the early 1950s – Stalin was forced to hand over complete control of certain
jurisdictions to this leadership substratum. Rather than being an inherently
stable or inert form of rule, Stalin’s one-man dictatorship was repeatedly in
tension with powerful oligarchic tendencies.
6
Maintaining the upper hand
3 See Alec Nove, Was Stalin Really Necessary? Some Problems of Soviet Political Economy
(London: George Allen and Unwin, 1964), pp. 27–32.
4 For an alternative view, which lends greater weight to the irrational aspects of Stalin’s
behaviour, see Roy Medvedev, Let History Judge: The Origins and Consequences of Stalinism,
revised edn (New York: Oxford University Press, 1989).
5 An early version of this argument may be found in T. H. Rigby, ‘Was Stalin a Disloyal
Patron?’ Soviet Studies 38, 3 (1986): 311–24.
6 Oligarchy is classically viewed as inherently unstable and displaying a propensity to
dissolve either into a pattern of individual dominance or into a more diffuse distribution
of power. Under Stalin, however, one detects repeated shifts in the opposite direction,
from one-man dictatorship towards oligarchical forms of decision-making. Cf. T. H.
Rigby, ‘The Soviet Leadership: Towards a Self-Stabilizing Oligarchy?’ Soviet Studies 22, 2
(1970): 167–8.
244