Lawrence Goldman
rejected the democratic principle, which could become the tyranny of the
majority: ‘It is said that twenty-four millions ought to prevail over two
hundred thousand. True; if the constitution of a kingdom be a problem of
arithmetic’ (Burke 2003,p.44).
While conservatism in the second half of the nineteenth century focused
on other themes beyond this Burkean inheritance, and while we must note
that this form of Anglo-Saxon conservatism cannot stand for all types, the
essence was always, as in Burke’s case, anti-revolutionary. And that anti-
revolutionary case usually comprised some at least of Burke’s arguments
(Muller 1977,p.25). Nineteenth-century conservatives stressed human
imperfection; they counselled, therefore, an epistemological caution because
we cannot know all we need to know, or would like to know, in fashioning
society. They placed their faith in institutions, whether religious or secular,
as necessary restraints on human irresponsibility. Pace Rousseau, men were
civilised by institutions rather than enchained by them: they were born bad
rather than free. Hence the utility of religion: while many conservatives
embraced Christianity in true faith, others saw its usefulness in impos-
ing moral, and by extension, political restraints on men and women, and
reminding them of their fallen nature. That social institutions had endured
was taken as evidence of their fitness for purpose rather than a reason for their
reform: the past was a surer guide to political wisdom than the unknown
future that liberalism rushed to embrace. According to Chateaubriand, ‘The
past is a fact, a fact that cannot be destroyed; while the future, which is so
dear to us, does not exist.’
4
Conservatives were suspicious of theorising,
both because no theory can account for the vagaries of human will, and
because theories applied to the crooked timber of humanity must ignore the
historic, the local, and specific, and might then become tyrannous. Thus
the universalist deductions of nineteenth-century liberal political economy
were as much anathema to the conservative as to the socialist: in figures like
Thomas Carlyle and John Ruskin moral and emotional opposition to lib-
eral economics led to an ambiguous stance, allowing them to be claimed by
both left and right. Conservatives were suspicious of liberal contractualism
as a way of understanding and organising society because this degraded the
complex relations and loyalties that held actual societies together. The use of
organic imagery in conservative discourse (‘webs’, ‘skeins’, ‘nets’, ‘f abrics’)
was an affirmation of the interdependence of social groups and institutions,
and an implied critique of those who would disturb the complex work
4 ‘
´
Etudes Historiques’, Chateaubriand 1859,pp.21–2, quoted in Tholfsen 1967,p.188.
694