linda t. darling
regions and 42 per cent in Anatolia and the Arab lands. The large and lucrative
Aegean and Balkan investments came mostly from janissaries and central state
elites, while the smaller Anatolian and Arab investments were held by a wider
mix of local Muslim elites. Non-Muslims were not permitted to hold malik
ˆ
anes,
but continued to participate in state finances as ordinary tax-farmers. The most
profitable investments were the customs dues and excise taxes, whose high
levels of return reflect the growing prosperity of the mid-eighteenth century,
the dividends of peace and the increase in trade with Europe. Eighty per cent
of this wealth was controlled by a few hundred members of the central elite
whose large households, extensive provincial connections and ability to amass
capital and creditmade them the major players in the malik
ˆ
ane field.
32
To spread
the risk, these large holders began to sell shares of their lifetime tax-farms to
others and to diversify their holdings among a number of malik
ˆ
anes as well as
other forms of investment.
33
Credit was handled by a group of non-Muslim
moneychangers (sarraf), who registered with the treasury as guarantors of the
lifetime tax-farmers’ payments; they also handled loans and fund transfers via
bills of exchange.
34
The malik
ˆ
ane system in some cases encouraged greater investment in the
income-producing properties of the empire. Examples include the establish-
ment of a dye-works in Tokat by the holder of the stamp tax on cloth and
improvements to the dye-house of Aleppo.
35
But it was often true that holders
in Istanbul could not be brought to care about affairs in a distant provincial
malik
ˆ
ane or used their lifetime tax-farm merely as an investment receptacle
for wealth from other sources.
36
As shareholders multiplied, they gained the
right to manage their own shares of the malik
ˆ
ane or farm them out to still
more managers, further distancing the state from the productive classes. The
participation of local notables in the system strengthened the involvement
of provincial urban residents in the rural economy, but mainly through debt
patronage rather than agricultural investment.
37
In urban areas artisanal taxes
32 Ibid., p. 282. 33 C¸ izakc¸a, Comparative Evolution,p.171.
34 Salzmann, ‘Measures’, pp. 195–202; Pamuk, Monetary History,pp.200–4.
35 Mehmet Genc¸, ‘Ottoman Industry in the Eighteenth Century: General Framework,
Characteristics, and Main Trends’, in Manufacturing in the Ottoman Empire and Turkey,
1500–1950, ed. Donald Quataert (Albany, 1994), pp. 59–86,atp.61; Jean-Pierre Thieck,
‘D
´
ecentralisation ottomane et affirmation urbaine
`
a Alep
`
a la fin du XVIII
`
eme si
`
ecle’,
in Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbaines au Machreq, ed. Mona Zakaria et al.
(Beirut, 1985), pp. 117–68,atp.129.
36 C¸ izakc¸a, Comparative Evolution,p.172.
37 Ariel C. Salzmann, ‘Privatising the Empire: Pashas and Gentry during the Ottoman 18th
Century’, in The Great Ottoman Turkish Civilisation, ed. Kemal C¸ic¸ek, 4 vols. (Istanbul,
2000), vol. III, at pp. 132–9,pp.135–6.
128
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008