Public finances: the role of the Ottoman centre
state’s inability to alter the annual returns and an extra tax (cebel
¨
u bedeliyesi,
‘armed man substitute’) during wartime. The malik
ˆ
ane system constituted a
form of long-term borrowing by the state, secured against tax revenues.
The rising prices of the early 1700s made the malik
ˆ
ane system extremely
profitable for the holders, whose obligations remained static while their prof-
its grew. The practice quickly expanded beyond its original boundaries. By
1703, 1,442 holders had invested 361,835 kurus¸ in the Syrian and eastern Ana-
tolian provinces named in the edict, 322,278 kurus¸ in the Balkans and 213,592
kurus¸ in western Anatolia, amounting to about 40 per cent of total farmed
revenues.
27
Not only agricultural lands but flocks and tribal taxes, customs
dues and industrial revenues were all subject to malik
ˆ
ane, and it also spread to
revenues other than the sultan’s. The hass of the commander of the bor-
der defences at Temes¸var was being given in malik
ˆ
ane as early as 1704.
28
The majority of malik
ˆ
ane-holders were members of the central state elites
based in Istanbul, but most of the sub-farmers with whom they worked
were local officials and notables; through these financial ties the ayan in the
provinces improved their access to central power politics. At the same time,
the crucial roles in what became a gigantic financial and credit structure
were reserved for state elites, who held the largest malik
ˆ
anes.
29
Since the
latter seemed like private property, the holders often refused to pay to the
treasury the revenues that were due. Sub-farmers, unknown to the state,
took their shares from the revenues as well, unduly increasing the burden
on the taxpayers. The malik
ˆ
anes were serbest, or free from government
oversight, and peasants could not hope for protection from government
personnel.
30
Because of abuses such as these, the grand vizier in 1715 elim-
inated all malik
ˆ
anes except those mentioned in the original edict, returning
the revenues to the regular tax-farming system.
In 1717, however, the malik
ˆ
anes were reinstated and expanded, and rising
levels of prosperity permitted the government to raise the amounts due as
well. Total sales in 1722 (measured in muaccele) amounted to 1.45 million kurus¸,
in 1745 to 4.34 million, in 1768 to 9.78 million, and in 1787 to 13.16 million.
31
This
wealth supported the luxury and brilliance of the Ottoman court in the Tulip
Era and funded the several small wars of the period without budgetary deficits.
In 1741, 58 per cent of malik
ˆ
ane investments were in the Aegean and Balkan
27 Salzmann, ‘Measures’, pp. 172–3; of these 1,442 holders, 222 invested in the Balkans, 180
in Anatolia, and 1,040 in the rest of the empire.
28 Yavuz Cezar, Osmanlı maliyesinde bunalım ve de
˘
gis¸im d
¨
onemi (XVIII. yy’ dan Tanzimat’a
mali tarih) (Istanbul, 1986), p. 43.
29 Salzmann, ‘Measures’, pp. 149, 168. 30 Belin, Essais,pp.179–80.
31 Genc¸, ‘Osmanlı maliyesinde malik
ˆ
ane’, p. 282.
127
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008