194 Selected Cash and Derivative Instruments
of the next period forward, and so on. The tree is called binomial because
at each future state, or node, there are precisely two possible paths ending
in two possible interest rates for the next period forward.
Arbitrage-Free Pricing
Assume that the current six-month and one-year rates are 5.00 and 5.15
percent, respectively. Assume further that six months from now the six-
month rate will be either 5.01 or 5.50 percent, and that each rate has a 50
percent probability of occurring. Bonds in this hypothetical market pay
semiannual coupons, as they do in the U.S. and U.K. domestic markets.
This situation is illustrated in
FIGURE 11.2.
Figure 11.2 is a one-period binomial interest rate tree, or lattice, for
the six-month interest rate. From this lattice, the prices of six-month and
1-year zero-coupon bonds can be calculated. As discussed in chapter 3,
the current price of a bond is equal to the sum of the present values of
its future cash fl ows. The six-month bond has only one future cash fl ow:
its redemption payment at face value, or 100. The discount rate to derive
the present value of this cash fl ow is the six-month rate in effect at point
0. This is known to be 5 percent, so the current six-month zero-coupon
bond price is 100/(1 + [0.05/2]), or 97.56098. The price tree for the six-
month zero-coupon bond is shown in
FIGURE 11.3.
For the six-month zero-coupon bond, all the factors necessary for pric-
ing—the cash fl ow and the discount rate—are known. In other words, only
one “world state” has to be considered. The situation is different for the one-
year zero coupon, whose binomial price lattice is shown in
FIGURE 11.4.
Deriving the one-year bond’s price at period 0 is straightforward. Once
again, there is only one future cash fl ow—the period 2 redemption pay-
ment at face value, or 100—and one possible discount rate: the one-year
interest rate at period 0, or 5.15 percent. Accordingly, the price of the one-
year zero-coupon bond at point 0 is 100/(1 + [0.0515/2]
2
), or 95.0423.
At period 1, when the same bond is a six-month piece of paper, it has
two possible prices, as shown in fi gure 11.4, which correspond to the two
possible six-month rates at the time: 5.50 and 5.01 percent. Since each
interest rate, and so each price, has a 50 percent probability of occurring,
the average, or expected value, of the one-year bond at period 1 is [(0.5 ×
97.3236) + (0.5 × 97.5562)], or 97.4399.
Using this expected price at period 1 and a discount rate of 5 percent
(the six-month rate at point 0), the bond’s present value at period 0 is
97.4399/(1 + 0.05/2), or 95.06332. As shown above, however, the market
price is 95.0423. This demonstrates a very important principle in fi nancial
economics: markets do not price derivative instruments based on their
expected future value. At period 0, the one-year zero-coupon bond is a